未来能源研究所-城市水价中的效率、公平和成本回收权衡 Efficiency,Equity,and Cost- Recovery Trade-Offs in Municipal Water Pricing 2024_第1页
未来能源研究所-城市水价中的效率、公平和成本回收权衡 Efficiency,Equity,and Cost- Recovery Trade-Offs in Municipal Water Pricing 2024_第2页
未来能源研究所-城市水价中的效率、公平和成本回收权衡 Efficiency,Equity,and Cost- Recovery Trade-Offs in Municipal Water Pricing 2024_第3页
未来能源研究所-城市水价中的效率、公平和成本回收权衡 Efficiency,Equity,and Cost- Recovery Trade-Offs in Municipal Water Pricing 2024_第4页
未来能源研究所-城市水价中的效率、公平和成本回收权衡 Efficiency,Equity,and Cost- Recovery Trade-Offs in Municipal Water Pricing 2024_第5页
已阅读5页,还剩111页未读 继续免费阅读

下载本文档

版权说明:本文档由用户提供并上传,收益归属内容提供方,若内容存在侵权,请进行举报或认领

文档简介

Efficiency,Equity,andCost-

RecoveryTrade-OffsinMunicipalWaterPricing

CaseyJ.Wichman

WorkingPaper24-18

October2024

AbouttheAuthor

CaseyWichmanisanassociateprofessorintheSchoolofEconomicsattheGeorgiaInstituteofTechnologyandauniversityfellowatResourcesfortheFuture.Heisanappliedmicroeconomistworkingonissuesattheintersectionofenvironmentaland

publiceconomics.Hisresearchfocusesonhowpeopleinteractwiththenaturalandbuiltenvironment,andwhatthatbehaviorrevealsaboutthevalueofenvironmental

amenities.Wichman’sresearchspanswaterandenergydemandmanagement,climatechangeimpactsandpolicy,urbantransportation,publicgoodsprovision,andoutdoorrecreation.

Acknowledgements

IthankDylanBrewer,NathanChan,TeevratGarg,LudovicaGazze,BenGilbert,

JoshGraffZivin,ArikLevinson,SheilaOlmstead,IvanRudik,BlakeShaffer,Steven

Smith,ChrisTimmins,WillWheeler,DerekWietelman,andconferenceandseminar

participantsattheTriangleResourceandEnvironmentalEconomicsseminar,ColoradoSchoolofMines,UniversityofAlabama,UniversityofCalgary,UCSanDiego,

UniversityofHouston,UniversityofWyoming,thePropertyandEnvironmentResearchCenter

(PERC),theYoungScholarsSymposiumonNaturalResourceGovernanceatIndianaUniversity,aswellasthe2023ASSA,AERE,andSEAmeetingsforhelpfulfeedback.ThisresearchwaspartiallysupportedbyagrantfromtheGeorgiaTechStrategicPlanAdvisoryGroupandtheLoneMountainFellowshipatPERC.TurnerStevensprovidedexceptionalresearchassistance.

ResourcesfortheFuturei

AboutRFF

ResourcesfortheFuture(RFF)isanindependent,nonprofitresearchinstitutionin

Washington,DC.Itsmissionistoimproveenvironmental,energy,andnaturalresourcedecisionsthroughimpartialeconomicresearchandpolicyengagement.RFFis

committedtobeingthemostwidelytrustedsourceofresearchinsightsandpolicysolutionsleadingtoahealthyenvironmentandathrivingeconomy.

Workingpapersareresearchmaterialscirculatedbytheirauthorsforpurposesof

informationanddiscussion.Theyhavenotnecessarilyundergoneformalpeerreview.TheviewsexpressedherearethoseoftheindividualauthorsandmaydifferfromthoseofotherRFFexperts,itsofficers,oritsdirectors.

SharingOurWork

OurworkisavailableforsharingandadaptationunderanAttribution-

NonCommercial-NoDerivatives4.0International(CCBY-NC-ND4.0)license.Youcancopyandredistributeourmaterialinanymediumorformat;youmustgive

appropriatecredit,providealinktothelicense,andindicateifchangesweremade,andyoumaynotapplyadditionalrestrictions.Youmaydosoinanyreasonable

manner,butnotinanywaythatsuggeststhelicensorendorsesyouoryouruse.Youmaynotusethematerialforcommercialpurposes.Ifyouremix,transform,orbuilduponthematerial,youmaynotdistributethemodifiedmaterial.Formoreinformation,visit

/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/

.

Efficiency,Equity,andCost-RecoveryTrade-OffsinMunicipalWaterPricing

Efficiency,Equity,andCost-RecoveryTrade-Offs

inMunicipalWaterPricing*

CaseyJ.Wichman†October11,2024

Abstract

Municipalwaterutilitieschooseratestorecovercosts,encourageconservation,andreduceburdensonlow-incomecustomers,whichmaydeviatefromoptimaltwo-parttariffs.Theorysuggeststhatpricesshouldequalmarginalcostwithfixedcostsrecoveredviafixedfeesoralternativetaxrevenues.Usingratestructureandmunicipalfinancedataformorethan700utilities,Ishowthatpricesarediscountedseverelyforlowlevelsofconsumptionwithinnonlinearratestructures,leadingtosuboptimalusageandbudgetdeficits,particularlyinpoorerandsmallercommunities.Marginal-costpricingcorrectsallocativeinefficiencies,andequityandcost-recoverygoalscanbeachievedthroughmoreprogressiveapproachestofixedcosts,whicharebothhighlyregressiveandalargeshareoftotalcosts.

KeyWords:waterpricing;utilitymanagement;naturalmonopolies;two-parttariffs;nonlin-earpricing;affordability;municipalfinance.

JELcodes:D12,H23,L95,Q25

*IthankDylanBrewer,NathanChan,TeevratGarg,LudovicaGazze,BenGilbert,JoshGraffZivin,ArikLevinson,SheilaOlmstead,IvanRudik,BlakeShaffer,StevenSmith,ChrisTimmins,WillWheeler,DerekWietelman,andcon-ferenceandseminarparticipantsattheTriangleResourceandEnvironmentalEconomicsseminar,ColoradoSchoolofMines,UniversityofAlabama,UniversityofCalgary,UCSanDiego,UniversityofHouston,UniversityofWyoming,thePropertyandEnvironmentResearchCenter(PERC),theYoungScholarsSymposiumonNaturalResourceGover-nanceatIndianaUniversity,aswellasthe2023ASSA,AERE,andSEAmeetingsforhelpfulfeedback.ThisresearchwaspartiallysupportedbyagrantfromtheGeorgiaTechStrategicPlanAdvisoryGroupandtheLoneMountainFellowshipatPERC.TurnerStevensprovidedexceptionalresearchassistance.

†Wichman:AssociateProfessor,SchoolofEconomics,GeorgiaInstituteofTechnology,221BobbyDoddWay,Atlanta,GA30332.Email:

wichman@;UniversityFellow,ResourcesfortheFuture

.

1

1Introduction

Municipalwaterandwastewaterutilitiesaretaskedwiththeoperationofcriticalinfrastructureforthewell-beingoftheirresidents:deliveringclean,safe,andreliabledrinkingwaterandre-turningittonaturalwaterbodieswithoutharmingtheenvironment.Duetopoliticalpressure,concernsaboutaffordability,andtheUnitedNations’declarationthataccesstowaterisahu-

manright(UNGeneralAssembly,

2010),waterpricestypicallydonotreflectthetruecostof

service(Hanemann,

1997;

Timmins,

2002b;

Olmstead,

2010)

.Failuretorecovercostscanprevent

utilitiesfrominvestingininfrastructureandmaintainingservicequality(McRae,

2015)

.Evenindevelopedcountries,poorfiscalmanagementcanresultincatastrophicconsequences,suchas

recentservicefailuresinJackson,MS,1

orFlint,MI(Christensenetal.,

2023)

.Efficiencysuggeststhatpricesshouldequallong-runmarginalcostsofprovision,bututilities—–largelyoperatedbyfinanciallyandpoliticallyconstrainedmunicipalgovernments—–needtobalanceequityconsid-erationswithrevenueneedsandclearmarketsignals

.2

Inbalancingthesegoals,utilitiesoften

adoptnonlinearratestructuresthatdiscountmarginalpricesforlowlevelsofconsumption(Olm-

steadetal.,

2007;

Szabo,

2015;

WangandWolak,

2022;

AllaireandDinar,

2022),althoughthese

pricingdecisionsmaygenerateallocativeinefficiencies(Borenstein,

2012,

2016;

Borensteinand

Davis,

2012),requiresubsidizationfromalternativemunicipalrevenuesources(Timmins,

2002a;

Renzetti,

1999),andineffectivelyredistributeincome(LevinsonandSilva,

2022;

Wietelmanetal.,

2024)

.

Ievaluatetheextenttowhichprevailingwaterpricesdeviatefromeconomicallyoptimalrates,whatdrivesthoseinefficiencies,andwhatimplicationsmispricedwaterserviceshaveonsocialwelfareandutilityrevenue.Ifirstrevisitclassictheoryontwo-partpricinginthespiritof

Coase

(1946),butIrefocusthisframeworkoncontemporaryissuesinmunicipalwaterandwastewater

pricing.Theframeworkdemonstratesthecanonicalefficiencyresultthatpriceshouldequalmarginalcost.However,unlikerecentresearchconcerningincreasing-blockrate(IBR)pricing

forprivate,regulatedelectricutilities(LevinsonandSilva,

2022),municipalmanagerscanrelax

theutility’sbudgetconstraintviaintragovernmentaltransfers.Inpractice,utilitiesoftenrundeficits(subsidizingwaterservicefromgeneralfundrevenue)orsurpluses(fundingotherlocalpublicgoodsthroughwaterrates),soassumingthatthezero-profitconditionholdsisrestrictive.Relaxingthisconstraintallowsmunicipalitiestodrawfromalternativesourcesofrevenuetorecoverfixedcosts.Fixedhouseholdservicefeesforwaterandwastewater—often$250–350peryearorapproximately40–50percentofwaterexpenditures—operateaslump-sumtaxesonhouseholds,whichislikelythemostregressiveformofrevenueraisedbylocalgovernments

.3

1See,forexample,

/news/2023/06/28/timeline-jackson-mississippi-water-problems.

(accessedJune19,2024).

2Approximately150,000USwatersystemsintheUnitedStatesprovidewaterandwastewaterservicesto90

percentoftheUSpopulation;thevastmajorityofthesearepubliclyowned(/dwreginfo/

information-about-public-water-systems)

.

3Fixedaccessfeesdonotvarybyincome.Propertyandsalestaxes,thetwomostlikelysourcesofmunicipalrevenue,arealsoregressive,butconsumptionandpropertyvaluestendtoincrease,albeitlessthanproportionally,withincome.

2

Waterutilitiesthatcareaboutequitycansetthevolumetricrateequaltomarginalcostand,todealwithredistributionandrecoupfixedcosts,theycansetanindividualizedfixedmonthlyservicefeethattargetsdifferencesinincome(e.g.,bysettingservicefeesproportionaltopropertyvalues)orrelyonlessregressivesourcesofmunicipalrevenue.

Empirically,Iexplorewhetherwaterpricesdeviatefromoptimaltwo-parttariffsusingmorethanadecadeofannualdataonutilityratestructuresandmunicipalfinanceinformationformorethan700utilitiesintheSoutheasternUnitedStates

.4

Iprovideevidencethatutilitiesfailtobalancetheirbudgetexactlyand,onaverage,pricewaterbelowaveragecost.Usingvariationinoperatingexpendituresovertimeandacrossutilitiesinsimilarhydrologicregions,Iestimatemarginalcostsforwaterandwastewaterservicesandusetheseestimatestoevaluatehowmuchutilitiesdiscountormarkupwaterrates,accountingfornonlinearitiesintheratestructure.ThepredominantratestructuresareIBRsanduniformratesthatincludeanallocationofwateratzeromarginalprice(“uniform+free”),bothofwhichdiscountvolumetricpricesseverelyforlowlevelsofuse,accountingfornearlyhalfoftheconsumptiondistribution.ThemedianpricediscountforutilitieswithIBRsinthefirsttier(0–3kgal/month)isapproximately34percent,withpricesinhighertiersmarkedupby5–27percentabovemarginalcost.Themedianutilitythatprovidesanallocationoffreewaterinitsuniformratestructurediscountspricesby65percentinthefirsttier,withapproximatelymarginal-costpricinginhighertiers.Utilitieswithpurelyuniformratespricewater,onaverage,closetomarginalcost.

Whydoutilitiessubsidizeasubstantialportionofconsumptionthroughdiscountedmarginalprices?Commonexplanationsarethatthemanagersareinfluencedbypoliticalpressuretokeep

priceslow(Timmins,

2002b)andprovidebasicwaterserviceatlowcostforlow-incomecus

-

tomers(Szabo,

2015),despitemaintainingalump-sumtransferinstrumentonthebillthatcan

addressequityand/oraffordabilityconcernsmoredirectlyandmoreeffectively.Iexplorethefactorsassociatedwithinefficientpricingbycomparingwaterratesandmarkupsacrossutili-tiesinsimilarhydrologicregions.Severalresultsemerge.First,volumetricsubsidiesaremuchmorecommoninsmallerutilities,whichhavehigheraveragecostsofservice;theirinabilitytocapitalizeoneconomiesofscalereducesthelikelihoodofpassingthefullcoststhroughtocus-tomers.Second,volumetricpricesarelowerandmoreheavilydiscountedforutilitieswithlargerlow-incomepopulations,whichisnotablebecauseitrevealsanefficiency–equitytrade-off:theseutilitiesaremorelikelytosubsidizevolumetricpricesratherthanalterthefixedservicefeeorcoverfixedcostsviamunicipalrevenue.Third,waterratesandmarkupsarelargerforcommu-nitieswithnewerhomes,morerenters,andahigherproportionofnon-Whiteresidents.Fourth,greaterhistoricaldroughtintensityincreasesvolumetricpricesbutnotmarkups,indicatingthatscarcityispotentiallypricedintowaterratesviahighermarginalcosts.Furthermore,Ishowthat

4MysampleincludesthevastmajorityofutilitiesinGeorgiaandNorthCarolina,whicharetheeighthandninthmostpopulousstates,respectively.Combined,theirpopulation(~21M)wouldrepresentthefourthlargeststate,afterCalifornia(~39M),Texas(~31M),andFlorida(~23M),comprising6–7percentoftheUSpopulation.Intermsofeconomicoutput,NorthCarolina’sGDPin2023was$626B,andGeorgia’swas$661;combined,theywouldbecomparabletoIndonesia,theNetherlands,Turkey,andSaudiArabiainworldeconomicoutput.

3

thesepricingdecisionsareconsequentialforutilityoperations:decreasesinfixedfeesandinvolumetricpricesinthelowesttierincreasethelikelihoodthatautilityfailstocoveritscosts.

Next,Iestimaterevenueelasticities,whichindirectlyrevealspriceelasticitiesofdemand,leveragingyear-to-yearvariationintheutility-levelpaneldataonrevenuesandratechanges.Iadoptaninstrumental-variable(IV)strategytoaccountfornonlinearratestructuresandpo-tentiallyendogenousratechangesusingratestructurecharacteristicsfromneighboringutilities.Theestimatedrevenueelasticitiessuggestthatforevery10percentincreaseinvolumetricprices,revenuesincreasebyapproximately4–5percent,whichimpliespriceelasticityestimatesof−0.5to−0.6.Usingtheseelasticitiesandtheestimatedmarginalcosts,Isimulaterevenueandsocialwelfareimplicationsofadoptingefficientpricing.Manyutilitiescanincreaserevenuebypricingatmarginalcost,whichislargelyadirectsurplustransferfromconsumers.Inmostcases,thatsurplusdeclinesduetoremovaloftheinframarginalvolumetricsubsidyimplicitinthenonlinearratestructures.Whetherconsumptionincreasesordecreasesdependsonthepresumedmodelofpriceperceptionandthewedgebetweenpricesandmarginalcosts.Marginalpricesaregenerallycloseto,orslightlylargerthan,marginalcost,whichimpliesthatconsumptionincreasesslightly

ifconsumersrespondtomarginalprice(Olmsteadetal.,

2007;

NatarajandHanemann,

2011)

.Forutilitieswithnonlinearratestructures,averagevolumetricpricestendtofallbelowmarginalcostsduetoinframarginaldiscounts,soconsumptiondecreasesifconsumersrespondtoaver-

ageprice(Ito,

2014;

Wichman,

2014;

BrentandWard,

2019;

Shaffer,

2020)

.Regardlessofpriceperception,nonlinearratesgenerateallocativeinefficiencies,whicharealleviatedbymarginal-costpricing.Forthemedianutility,marginal-costpricingeliminatesdeadweightlossandraisesrevenue,whichalmostoffsetsconsumersurpluslosses.Althoughthisispurelyanefficiencyresult,therevenuegainscanbeusedtoadvancedistributionalgoals,byeitheradoptinglower(orprogressive)fixedfeesorleveragingalternative,lessregressivesourcesofmunicipalrevenuetorecoverfixedcosts.

Thispapermakesseveralcontributionstoourunderstandingofinefficienciesinutilitypric-ing.Igeneratenewinsightsonnaturalmonopolypricingthatbalancesequity–efficiencytrade-offsanddocumentwidespreadpricinginefficienciesinthemunicipalwatersector.Thispaperaddstoalong-standinglineofinquiryonoptimalpricingformunicipalutilityservices,someofwhichisfocusedontheredistributionalimplicationsofnonlinearrates(e.g.,

Borenstein,

2012;

BorensteinandDavis,

2012;

LevinsonandSilva,

2022;

BorensteinandBushnell,

2022)

.Mostre-searchonwaterpricingadoptsmodelingframeworksfromenergypricing,butwaterutilitiesaredistinctfromenergyutilitiesinseveralimportantways.First,theytypicallyjointlymanageproduction,distribution,andtreatment,whichisatypicalofenergyutilities.Relatedly,becauseoftheprohibitivecostsofmovingwaterlongdistances,waterutilitiesaresmallerandmanagedmuchmorelocally.Bothofthesefactorslimittheirabilitytobenefitfromscaleeconomies

.5

Asaresult,percapitafixedcostsofwaterservice(and,hence,fixedcharges)arerelativelylarge

5Toemphasizethispoint,Georgiahas52municipallyownedelectricutilities,41electricmembershipcorporations,andoneinvestor-ownedutilitythatoperatesin155ofits159counties(source:

/utilities/

electric/)

.Bycontrast,Ianalyze382municipalwaterutilitiesinGeorgiathatserve,onaverage,5,000customers.

4

anddeservemoreexplicitattentioninwaterpricing.Second,waterutilitiesareoverwhelminglyoperatedbymunicipalgovernments,soratesareregulatedindirectlybyvotersandtypicallynotbyautilitycommission

.6

Thisstructureallowsutilitiestotapintoalternativesourcesofmunicipalrevenue,whicharelessregressivethanafixedlump-sumtaxtorecoverfixedcosts.Third,waterserviceprovidesmanylocalpublicgoods,suchaswaterprovisionforfireprotectionandstormwaterinfrastructureforfloodprotection,thatarefundedthroughutilitybillsandcan

rationalizemunicipalsubsidies(Beecher,

2020)

.

Thispaperalsocontributestoourunderstandingofnonlinearpricingforutilityservices.SeveralstudiesexploretheeffectsofIBRsforelectricity,naturalgas,andwateruseatthehouse-holdlevel(e.g.,

ReissandWhite,

2005;

Olmsteadetal.,

2007;

NatarajandHanemann,

2011;

Ito,

2014;

Wichman,

2014;

Szabo,

2015),butlittleworkhasfocusedonutility-wideconsequences,es

-peciallyforwaterandwastewaterservices

.7

Nonlinearratesarebeingincreasinglyadoptedforwater,largelyunderthebannerofachievingconservationandreducingburdensonlow-incomecustomers.ThisresearchhaslargelyfocusedonIBRs,butIadditionallyhighlightacommonhiddeninefficiencyinutilitypricingdecisions:manyutilitiespossessratestructuresthatembedanallocationoffreeconsumption(onaverage,1–3kgal/monthpercustomer).Thesenonlinearvolumetricratestructuresdonotreflectcosts,oftenrequiresubsidizationfromotherrevenuesources,andcanleadtosuboptimalconsumptionbydrivingawedgebetween(infra-)marginalpricesandmarginalcosts.Ishowthatuniform,marginal-costpricingcaneliminateallocativeinefficienciesandincreaserevenuebyremovingvolumetricsubsidies,whichcouldbeused,inprinciple,tolowerfixedfeesoroffsetthemwithlessregressivesourcesofmunicipalrevenue.

Last,comparativeanalysesofwaterutilitiesarerarebecausenocentralizedrepositoryofdatalinkswaterratestructureswithmunicipalrevenueandcostinformationforthesameutilitiesovertime.Mostresearchonmunicipalwaterpricingevaluatesconsumerresponsestopriceandratestructurechangesusingbillingdata—typicallyfocusingononeorasmallsetofutilities—withthegoalofestimatingpriceelasticitiesofdemand(e.g.,

Olmsteadetal.,

2007;

Olmstead,

2009;

MansurandOlmstead,

2012;

Baerenklauetal.,

2014;

Wichmanetal.,

2016;

El-Khattabietal.,

2021;

Smith,

2022)

.Incontrast,Icharacterizetheefficiencycostsofprevailingwaterpricingpracticesusingadecadeofwaterandwastewaterratestructuresmatchedwithadministrativedataonmunicipalfinancesformorethan700municipalutilities.Tomyknowledge,thedataassembledinthispaperisthemostextensivepaneldatasetofwaterutilityratestructureslinkedwithutilitycostsandrevenues.Thesedataallowmetoestimatemarginalcostsandcompareratestructure

characteristicsacrossutilitiesinvariedgeographicregions(i.e.,coastal,mountainous,urban,

6Privateorfor-profitbutnotmunicipalwaterutilitiesaretypicallyregulatedbystateutilitycommissions.

7ResearchhasaddressedthecomplicationsofIBRsbecausetheygeneratekinksinconsumerbudgetconstraints

(Hanemann,

1984)

.Structuraldiscrete-continuouschoicemodelshavebeenappliedtoestimatepriceelasticitiesofdemandforwaterandelectricity(e.g.,

HewittandHanemann,

1995;

Olmsteadetal.,

2007;

Olmstead,

2009;

Baerenklau

etal.,

2014;

Szabo,

2015;

McRae,

2015)

.However,researchershavealsoquestionedwhetherconsumersunderstandnonlinearratestructuresandprovidedevidence,forbothelectricityandwater,thatconsumersmightrespondto

average,ratherthanmarginal,prices(Ito,

2014;

Wichman,

2014;

BrentandWard,

2019;

Shaffer,

2020)

.Othershave

arguedthatconsumersdorespondtomarginalpriceifthechangesarelargeenough(NatarajandHanemann,

2011)

.

5

rural)andwithheterogeneousservicepopulations.Importantly,thedatasetincludeshundredsofsmall-andmedium-sizedwaterutilitiesthatarerarelyevaluatedineconomicsresearchdespitetheircentralroleindeliveringessentialservicestoresidentsoutsideoflargemetropolitanareas.

Renzetti

(1992),

Renzetti

(1999),and

Timmins

(2002b)areamongthefewpapersthatevaluate

theefficiencyconsequencesofmunicipalwater(andwastewater)prices,buttheyarebasedonnow-outdateddatasetswithlimitedgeographicortemporalscopeanddonotaccountfortherecent,increasingprevalenceofnonlinearratestructuresdespitethetrade-offsinherentinfixedversusvolumetricpricingdecisions.

2Conceptualframework

Inthissection,Ilayoutamodelofrate-settingformunicipalwaterutilities.Myapproachadoptsthegeneralframeworkof

LevinsonandSilva

(2022),whichanalyzestheredistributivepotential

ofnonlinearelectricitypricingbyextendingaformalmodelof

Coase

(1946),butIrefocusiton

theparticularsofmunicipalwaterandwastewaterutilities.

2.1Thehousehold’sproblem

Considerahouseholdthatmaximizesutilityoverwaterconsumption,wi,andanumerairegoodxi,wheresuperscriptsindexhouseholds(i=1,...,n).ThehouseholdearnsincomeMi,whichissubjecttoamarginaltaxrateofτ≥0andalump-sumgovernmenttransfergi(bothofwhichthehouseholdtakesasgiven).Thehouseholdspendsincomeonwater(atmarginalpricepwithafixedservicefeet≥0)andthenumerairegood(withpricenormalizedto1)inthepresentperiod,

leadingtothebudgetconstraintpwi+t+x=(1−τ)Mi+gi.Leti≡(1−τ)Mi+gi−ti

representafter-taxresidualincome.Thehousehold’sproblembecomes

maxui(wi,i−pwi).(1)

wiThehousehold’sfirst-orderconditionis

Thisconditionimplicitlydefinesdemandforwaterandthenumerairegood:wi(p,i)andxi(p,i)=−pwi(p,i).Pluggingthesedemandequationsintotheutilityfunctionresultsinthefollowingindirectutilityfunction:vi(p,i)=u(wi(p,i),xi(p,i))foralli=1,...,n.

2.2Thegovernment’sproblem

Thegovernmentchoosesprices,fixedfees,andmarginaltaxratestomaximizethesumofindirectutilityhouseholdsreceive.Itsroleisthefirstpointofdeparturefrom

LevinsonandSilva

(2022)

6

becausethemajorityofUSwaterutilitiesarepublicentitiesownedandoperatedbymunicipalgovernments;theyarelargelynotprivate,regulatednaturalmonopolies,suchasnaturalgasorelectricutilities.Thisdistinctionhasimportantimplicationsforbudgetbalancingandfixed-costrecoverythatIexploredirectly.

ThegovernmentmanagesawaterutilitythathasfixedcostsFandper-unitcostsc.So,thegovernment’stotalcostofsupplyingW=ΣiwiunitsofwaterisF+cΣiwi.Thegovernmentmustbalanceitsbudgeteachyear,resultinginthefollowingbudgetconstraint:

whereG=Σigiaretotalgovernmentaltransfers.Theleft-handsideofthisequationisgovern-mentalrevenue;theright-handsideisgovernmentalexpenditure.

2.2.1Aself-sufficientwaterutility

First,assumethegovernmentchoosespandtbuttreatsτasfixedandexogenousandthatτΣiMi=G,sothatitfocusesonlyonbalancingrevenueandcosts.ThisresultsinthesimplerbudgetconstraintΣi[t+pwi−cwi]=F,whichreducestothebaselinecasein

Levinsonand

Silva

(2022)

.Thesolution,outlinedindetailin

AppendixA,providesthecanonicalresultthat

priceshouldbesetequaltomarginalcost(p=c).Substitutingthisresultintothegovernment’sbudgetconstraintresultsinsettingfixedfeesequaltoaveragefixedcosts,or,t=F/n.

Ifthegovernmentcaninsteadsetindividualizedprices,pi—whichmightreflectpricediscrim-inationacrosscustomersorheterogeneousmarginalpricesacrosstheconsumptiondistribution(i.e.,IBRs)—theprimaryinsightdoesnotchange.Theoptimalpricingrulewhenindividualizedpricesarefeasibleresultsintheconditionthatpi=cforalli,orthatallunitsofconsumptionshouldbechargedthesamemarginalprice.Thisresult—thatmarginalpriceshouldbeequalacrosscustomersanduses—shouldbeuncontroversialtoeconomistsandsuggeststhatanypric-ingstructurethatdeviatesfrommarginal-costpricingwillbeinefficient.

Borenstein

(2012)claims

thatIBRsforelectricityhavenocostbasis,asIBRsassigndifferentmarginalpricestodifferent

customers,leadingtodifferentincentivestoconsumewater.8

LevinsonandSilva

(2022)additionallyshowthatifthegovernmentcaresaboutequityand

cansetindividualizedfixedservicefeesandmarginalprices,thenmarginalpriceshouldstillbesettoequaltomarginalcost,forallhouseholdsanduses,andthefeeusedtoredistributeincomecompletely(i.e.,ifhouseholdsdifferonlyintheirincomes,thenitwillbeusedtoequalizeincomeacrossallhouseholds).Ofcourse,fullyredistributingincomethroughautilitybillisanimpracti-calresult,althoughmilderversionsofthissolutionmayaidinredistributionwithoutsacrificing

efficiency.9

LevinsonandSilvausethisasapointofdeparturefromoptimaltwo-parttariffsto

8Hanemann

(1997),however,arguesthatIBRscouldbesupportedbyacostargument,inasmuchasblockrate

structures

温馨提示

  • 1. 本站所有资源如无特殊说明,都需要本地电脑安装OFFICE2007和PDF阅读器。图纸软件为CAD,CAXA,PROE,UG,SolidWorks等.压缩文件请下载最新的WinRAR软件解压。
  • 2. 本站的文档不包含任何第三方提供的附件图纸等,如果需要附件,请联系上传者。文件的所有权益归上传用户所有。
  • 3. 本站RAR压缩包中若带图纸,网页内容里面会有图纸预览,若没有图纸预览就没有图纸。
  • 4. 未经权益所有人同意不得将文件中的内容挪作商业或盈利用途。
  • 5. 人人文库网仅提供信息存储空间,仅对用户上传内容的表现方式做保护处理,对用户上传分享的文档内容本身不做任何修改或编辑,并不能对任何下载内容负责。
  • 6. 下载文件中如有侵权或不适当内容,请与我们联系,我们立即纠正。
  • 7. 本站不保证下载资源的准确性、安全性和完整性, 同时也不承担用户因使用这些下载资源对自己和他人造成任何形式的伤害或损失。

评论

0/150

提交评论