美联储-家庭过度储蓄与货币政策传导 Household Excess Savings and the Transmission of Monetary Policy 2024_第1页
美联储-家庭过度储蓄与货币政策传导 Household Excess Savings and the Transmission of Monetary Policy 2024_第2页
美联储-家庭过度储蓄与货币政策传导 Household Excess Savings and the Transmission of Monetary Policy 2024_第3页
美联储-家庭过度储蓄与货币政策传导 Household Excess Savings and the Transmission of Monetary Policy 2024_第4页
美联储-家庭过度储蓄与货币政策传导 Household Excess Savings and the Transmission of Monetary Policy 2024_第5页
已阅读5页,还剩59页未读 继续免费阅读

下载本文档

版权说明:本文档由用户提供并上传,收益归属内容提供方,若内容存在侵权,请进行举报或认领

文档简介

BoardofGovernorsoftheFederalReserveSystemInternationalFinanceDiscussionPapers

ISSN1073-2500(Print)ISSN2767-4509(Online)

Number1397

October2024

HouseholdExcessSavingsandtheTransmissionofMonetaryPolicy

ThiagoR.T.Ferreira,NilsGornemann,JulioL.Ortiz

Pleasecitethispaperas:

Ferreira,ThiagoR.T.,NilsGornemann,JulioL.Ortiz(2024).“HouseholdEx-cessSavingsandtheTransmissionofMonetaryPolicy,”InternationalFinanceDiscus-sionPapers1397.Washington:BoardofGovernorsoftheFederalReserveSystem,

/10.17016/IFDP.2024.1397

.

NOTE:InternationalFinanceDiscussionPapers(IFDPs)arepreliminarymaterialscirculatedtostimu-latediscussionandcriticalcomment.TheanalysisandconclusionssetfortharethoseoftheauthorsanddonotindicateconcurrencebyothermembersoftheresearchstafortheBoardofGovernors.ReferencesinpublicationstotheInternationalFinanceDiscussionPapersSeries(otherthanacknowledgement)shouldbeclearedwiththeauthor(s)toprotectthetentativecharacterofthesepapers.RecentIFDPsareavailableontheWebat/pubs/ifdp/.ThispapercanbedownloadedwithoutchargefromtheSocialScienceResearchNetworkelectroniclibraryat.

HouseholdExcessSavingsandthe

TransmissionofMonetaryPolicy*

ThiagoR.T.FerreiratNilsGornemann‡JulioL.Ortiz§

October8,2024

Abstract

HouseholdsavingsroseabovetrendinmanydevelopedcountriesaftertheonsetofCOVID-19.Givenitslinktoaggregateconsumption,thepresenceofthese“ex-cesssavings”hasraisedquestionsabouttheirimplicationsforthetransmissionofmonetarypolicy.Usingapanelofeuro-areaeconomiesandhigh-frequencymone-tarypolicyshocks,wedocumentthathouseholdexcesssavingsdampentheeffectsofmonetarypolicyoneconomicactivityandinflation,especiallyduringthepandemicperiod.Torationalizeourempiricalfindings,webuildaNewKeynesianmodelinwhichhouseholdsusesavingstoself-insureagainstcounter-cyclicalunemploymentandconsumptionrisk.

KeyWords:MonetaryPolicy,ExcessSavings,PrecautionarySavings,ConsumptionRisk,Unemployment

JELClassification:E12,E21,E24,E31,E52.

*WearegratefultoMitchLottforoutstandingresearchassistance.WealsothankMatteoIacoviello,PhillipJefferson,StevenOngena,ChristopherWaller,andpresentationattendeesattheFederalReserveBoardandthe2024IJCBconferencefortheircommentsandsuggestions.TheviewsexpressedinthispaperaresolelythoseoftheauthorsandshouldnotbeinterpretedasreflectingtheviewsoftheBoardofGovernorsoftheFederalReserveSystemorofanyotherpersonassociatedwiththeFederalReserve

Sys.eralReserveBoard,InternationalFinanceDivision;Washington,DC,20551,USA;Emailaddress:

thiago.r.teixeiraferreira@.

‡FederalReserveBoard,InternationalFinanceDivision;Washington,DC,20551,USA;Emailaddress:nils.m.gornemann@.

§FederalReserveBoard,InternationalFinanceDivision;Washington,DC,20551,USA;Emailaddress:julio.l.ortiz@.

1

1Introduction

DuringtheCOVID-19pandemic,householdsaroundtheworldaccumulatedlargestocksofsavingsthroughacombinationofprecautionarymotives,aninabilitytospendtheirfundsamidwidespreadlockdowns,andincreasedfiscalsupporttotheirincomes.Soonafter,themainconcernofpolicymakersquicklyswitchedfromalleviatingthelackofhouseholdincometofightingdecades-highinflation.Still,householdsmaintainedrobuststocksof“excesssavings”(i.e.,savingsinexcessoftrend),andpolicymakersbegantoquestiontheirpossibleeffectsonthetransmissionofmonetarypolicy.

1

Inthispaper,weevaluatetheeffectsofexcesssavingsonmonetarypolicytransmission,bothempiricallyandtheoretically.Wedocumentthatexcesssavingsineuro-areaeconomiesrosetohistoricallyhighlevelsduringthepandemicperiod.Then,usinghigh-frequencymonetarypolicyshocks,weestimatestate-dependenteffectsofmonetarypolicyusinglocalprojections(

Jord`a,

2005

),andwefindthatmonetarypolicytransmissiontobothinflationandeconomicactivityisdampenedinperiodsofhighexcesssavings.Finally,werationalizehowexcesssavingsaffectthetransmissionofmonetarypolicyusingaNewKeynesianmodelinwhichhouseholdsfaceidiosyncratic,countercyclicalunemploymentandconsumptionriskagainstwhichtheycanonlyself-insurethroughsavings.

Webeginbymeasuringthestockofexcesssavingsandmonetarypolicyshocksforeuro-areaeconomies.Inadditiontotheeuro-areaaggregate,ourempiricalanalysisfocusesonthefourlargesteuro-areacountries:Germany,Italy,France,andSpain.Following

deSoyreset

al.

(2023),wedefinehouseholdexcesssavingsastheamountofsavingsarisingfromabove

-trendhouseholdsavingsrates.Toestimatecountry-leveltrendsavingsrates,weemploythe

Hamilton

(2018)filter

.Ourmeasureofexcesssavingsexhibitsvariationacrosstimeandcountries,withthepandemicperiodshowinghistoricallyhighlevels.Tomeasurethemonetarypolicyshocks,weapplythehigh-frequencyapproachof

Buetal.

(

2021

)totheeuroarea,whichaccountsforthemixofpoliciesfromtheEuropeanCentralBank(ECB)focusedonbothpolicyratesandassetpurchases.

Aftermeasuringtheseobjects,weusethemtoestimatetheeffectsofmonetarypolicyonrealandnominaloutcomes.Wefocusontwovariablesofinterest:theunemploymentrateandconsumerpriceinflation.Weestimatetheeffectsofmonetarypolicyontheseoutcomes

ofinterestvialocalprojections.Ourestimatesrevealthattheeffectofacontractionary

1Forinstance,seethe

speech

byChristineLagarde,PresidentoftheEuropeanCentralBank,at“TheECBandItsWatchersXXIII”conference.

2

monetarypolicyshockonrealandnominaloutcomesofinterestisattenuatedwhenstocksofexcesssavingsarelarger.Wefindthatourresultsarerobustto(i)differentmeasuresofeconomicactivity,(ii)controllingforthebalancesheetstrengthofthebankingsystem,and(iii)time-specificchangesaroundtheCOVIDperiod.

Ourempiricalresultscanbesummarizedasfollows.Wefindthatacontractionarymonetarypolicyshockscaledtogeneratea50basispointincreaseinthetwo-yearGermangovernmentyieldraisestheunemploymentratebyabout0.30percentagepointwhenexcesssavingsareclosetozero,butonlybyabout0.15percentagepointwhenexcesssavingsarefixedtotheir2023Q1levels.Additionally,weshowthattwelve-monthheadlineinflationdeclinesbynearly0.40percentagepointwhenexcesssavingsareclosetozero,butonlybyabout0.30percentagepointwhenexcesssavingsareconsistentwiththeirobserved2023Q1levels.Wechoosetoevaluatetheefficacyofmonetarypolicyin2023Q1becauseeuro-areaheadlineinflationpeakedaroundthistime,therebyconstitutingamomentatwhichpolicymakerspaidheightenedattentiontotheeffectivenessofmonetarypolicygoingforward.

Motivatedbyourempiricalfindings,webuildasimpleNewKeynesianmodelwithunemploymentandimperfectinsuranceagainstindividualunemploymentrisk.RelativetothestandardrepresentativeagentNewKeynesiansetting,savingsinourmodelarevaluedbecausetheyallowworkerstoself-insureagainsttheconsumptionriskofbeingunemployed.Unemploymentriskrisesduringcontractions,inducingworkerstocutbackconsumptionfurtheratthestartofadownturntosavemore.Thisresponseamplifiesthedirectimpactofanycontractionaryshock.Highersavingsattheonsetofthedownturnreducethiscon-sumptionresponseandthereforeleadtolessamplification.Asaresult,consistentwithourempiricalfindings,acalibratedversionofourmodelgeneratesdampenedrealandnominalresponsestomonetarypolicyshocksinahigh-savingseconomyrelativetothebaselineeconomy.Intotal,ourempiricalandquantitativeresultspointtoaneconomicallymean-ingfulnonlinearityinthepotencyofmonetarypolicybasedonthelevelofstocksofexcesssavings.

Ourpaperrelatestotherecentliteraturemeasuringexcesssavingsandstudyingtheiraggregateimplications.Ourmethodformeasuringexcesssavingsfollows

deSoyresetal.

(2023)

.Alternativeapproachestomeasuringexcesssavingsinclude

Aladangadyetal.

(2022)

and

AbdelrahmanandOliveira

(2023)

.Wetakeatime-varyingfilteringapproachbecauseitbestsuitsourpurposeofestimatingtheeffectsofmonetarypolicyshocksinapanelofeuro-areaeconomieswitharichtimedimension.Additionally,thereareotherrecent

3

studiesevaluatingtheeffectsofexcesssavingsaccumulatedduringCOVID-19.

Auclert

etal.

(2023)analyzestheprocessbywhichhouseholdexcesssavingsaffectthelevelof

aggregatedemand,andhowthisprocessvariesbasedonthedistributionofexcesssavings.

Aggarwaletal.

(2023)studydebt-financedfiscaltransfersinamodeloftheworldeconomy

thatreproduceslargefiscaldeficits,largeincreasesinprivatesavings,andpersistentcurrentaccountdeficits.Wecontributetothisliteraturebyempiricallyandquantitativelylinkingaggregateexcesssavingstomonetarypolicyeffectivenessinthecontextoftheeuroarea.

Ourpaperalsorelatestotheliteratureonthehowmonetarypolicytransmitstohouseholds.Recentcontributions,suchasthosemadeby

Cloyneetal.

(2020),findthat

mortgagorsaremoresensitivetomonetarypolicythanoutrightownersbecausethefor-merhavelittleliquidwealth.Inaddition,

HardingandKlein

(2022)and

Alpandaetal.

(2021)findempiricallythatmonetarypolicyismoreeffectiveinaffectingthemacroecon

-omywhenhouseholddebtisrisingorhigh

.2

Onthemodelingsideourpaperrelatestohouseholdmodelsofprecautionarysavingsdemandinthepresenceofcountercyclicalid-iosyncraticrisk,suchas

AcharyaandDogra

(2020),

Bilbiie

(2018),

Challeetal.

(2017),

Cho

(2023),

DenHaanetal.

(2018),

Gornemannetal.

(

2016

),and

RavnandSterk

(

2017

).Theempiricalstatedependencewedocumentcanbeviewedassupportiveofthemechanismsinthesepapers.Ourpaperissimilartothem,thoughitstudiesstatedependenthouseholdresponsivenesstomonetarypolicyacrossmajoreuro-areacountriesandinthecontextofexcesssavingsratherthanhouseholddebtornetworth.Ourmeasureofexcesssavings,particularlyaroundCOVID-19,likelyreflectsaninfluxofliquidsavingsthatallowedmanyEuropeanhouseholdstoremainclearofborrowingconstraintsduringtherecenttighteningcycle.

Therestofthepaperisorganizedasfollows.Section

2

discussesthedatausedforourempiricalanalysis–particularlyourmeasuresofexcesssavingsandeuro-areamonetarypolicyshocks.Section

3

reportsourempiricalresults,whichshowthattheeffectsofmon-etarypolicyaredampenedwhenstocksofhouseholdexcesssavingsarehigh.Section

4

explorestheeconomicmechanismthroughwhichexcesssavingsaffectthetransmissionofmonetarypolicyinasimpleNewKeynesianmodelandpresentssimulationsrationalizingourempiricalresults.Section

5

concludes.

2

HardingandKlein

(2022)provideanalternativemechanismtorationalizeourfindings

.Intheirmodel,highersavingswouldrelaxacollateralconstraint,leadingtoadampeningofcontractionaryshockswhenconstrainedagentscutbackonconsumption.Weviewourmechanismascomplementarytotheirs.

4

2DataDescription

Inthissection,wedescribehowwemeasurethestocksofexcesssavingsandmonetarypolicyshocksusedforourempiricalresults.Appendix

A

providesfurtherdetailsonthedatausedinouranalysis.

2.1ExcessSavingsintheEuroArea

Figure1

StockofExcessSavingsintheEuroArea

Note:Figure

1

showstheseriesofstocksofexcesssavingsfortheeuro-areaaggregate(red),France(pink),Germany(blue),Italy(yellow),andSpain(green).

Wefollow

deSoyresetal.

(2023)bydefiningthestockofexcesssavingsastheamount

ofassets,asapercentofGDP,arisingfromabove-trendsavingsrates.First,foreachcountry,weextractatrendofthesavingsrateusingthe

Hamilton

(

2018

)filter

.3

Wethenusethedetrendedsavingsratetocalculatetheflowofexcesssavingsforcountryiinquartert,ineuros,asfollows:

Flowofexcesssavingsit=(DetrendedSavingsRateit)×(DisposableIncomeit).(1)

Toconstructthemeasureofthestockofexcesssavings,wecalculatethecumulativesum3Following

Hamilton

(2018),wedetrendthesavingsratecountrybycountryviaaregressionofthe

savingsrateonlags8to11.Theresidualisthedetrendedsavingsrate.

5

oftheflowsdefinedinequation(

1

)andnormalizeitbynominalGDP:

Stockofexcesssavingsit=×100.(2)

Finally,wedemeantheseriesatthecountrylevelovertheentiresampleperiod,whichspansfrom1999Q1through2023Q2

.4

Byconstruction,thestockofexcesssavingsincreaseswhentheflowofexcesssavingsispositive,whilethestockofexcesssavingsdecreaseswhentheflowofexcesssavingsisnegative.

Thismeasureofaggregateexcesssavingshassomeadvantages.First,itsconstruc-tionrequiresonlyaggregatenominalhouseholdsavings,disposableincome,andnominalGDP,allofwhicharereadilyavailableforavarietyofeuro-areacountries.Second,ourmethodologyproducesafulltimeseriesofestimatedexcesssavings,allowingustoexploititsvariationovertimeinouranalysis.Finally,despiteusingnominalhouseholdsavingsasaninput,ourmeasuredoesnotrelyontheassumptionthatpricesremainattheirtrends.

Ourmeasureofthestockofexcesssavingsfortheeuroareaexhibitsconsiderablevariation,bothinthetimeseriesandacrosscountries.Figure

1

showsthatinthelead-uptothe2008–2009GlobalFinancialCrisis,differenteconomieshaddifferenttrajectories,withItalyincreasingitsexcesssavings,FranceandGermanymaintainingtheirexcesssavings,andSpainandtheeuro-areaaggregatedecreasingtheirsavings.Incontrast,from2012to2020,mostoftheseeconomiesrandowntheirexcesssavings,withtheexceptionofFrance.Finally,amidtheCOVID-19pandemic,alloftheseeconomiessawtheirstocksofexcesssavingssharplyincrease.

2.2Euro-AreaHigh-FrequencyMonetaryPolicyShocks

Weapplythemethodologyof

Buetal.

(2021)tocalculatehigh-frequencymonetarypolicy

shocksfortheeuroarea.Specifically,weusedailydatafromtheGermanTreasuryyieldcurveforthemonetarypolicymeetingsoftheECBfortheperiodbetweenJanuary1999throughSeptember2022inourapplication.Figure

2

displaysthemonetarypolicyshocksthatarecalculatedusingthismethodology.Forourregressions,weaggregatetheseshocks

4Wedemeanthestockofexcesssavingswithincountrytoensurethatourempiricalresults,whichwedescribeinSection

3

,arenotdrivenbypermanentheterogeneityinexcesssavingsstemmingfrominitialconditionswhenaccumulatingthesavingsflowsovertime.

6

Figure2

MonetaryPolicyShocksfromtheEuropeanCentralBank

.2

.1

0

-.1

-.2

MonetaryPolicyShocksinPercentagePoints

20002005201020152020

Note:Figure

2

showsthetimeseriesofmonetarypolicyshockscalculatedusingGermanTreasuryyieldcurveforthemonetarypolicymeetingsoftheEuropeanCentralBankfortheperiodbetweenJanuary1999toSeptember2022.

bysummingthemtoamonthlyfrequency.

5

Ourchosenapproachtomeasuringmonetarypolicyshockscombinesthreeimportantfeaturesthataddressissuesextensivelydiscussedintheliterature.First,theshocksbridgeperiodsofconventionalandunconventionalmonetarypolicybyusinginterestratemove-mentsfromtheentireTreasuryyieldcurve.Second,

Buetal.

(

2021

)provideevidencethatthismethodologyremovesthecentralbankinformationeffectfortheUnitedStates:mon-etarypolicyannouncementsmayrevealinformationaboutthestateofthemacroeconomy,insteadofrepresentingonlygenuinemonetarypolicysurprises.Third,

Buetal.

(

2021

)documentthattheirU.S.monetarypolicyshocksarenotpredictedbyavailableinforma-tionontheeconomy,suchasBlueChipforecasts,newsreleases,andconsumersentiment

.6

Followingthesameapproach,inAppendix

B.1

weprovideevidencethatoureuroareamonetarypolicyshocksarenotpredictedbyinformationavailableinrealtime.

5WhenanalyzingtheconsumptionresponsetomonetarypolicyinAppendix

B.2

,weaggregatethemonetarypolicyshockstoaquarterlyfrequency.

6Formorediscussionoftheseissues,see

Miranda-Agrippino

(2016)and

BauerandSwanson

(2020)

.

7

3EmpiricalResults

Inthissection,weuseourmeasuresofexcesssavingsandeuro-areamonetarypolicyshockstodocumentthatexcesssavingsdampenthetransmissionofmonetarypolicytobotheconomicactivityandinflation.

3.1RegressionSpecifications

OursamplerunsfromJanuary1999throughSeptember2022andcoversfiveeconomies:theeuro-areaaggregate,Germany,France,Italy,andSpain.Werepresentaneconomywith

iandagivenmonthwitht.Theeuro-areamonetarypolicyshockisdenotedbyεand

isscaledsuchthattheshockgeneratesa50basispointincreaseinthetwo-yearGermangovernmentbondyield.Forallregressions,wealsospecifyasetofcountry-specificandeuro-area-specificcontrolsdenotedbyZit.Thecountry-specificcontrolsare12lagsofinflationrates,unemploymentrates,industrialproduction,GDPgrowth,andaninteractionofGDPgrowthwiththemonetarypolicyshocktoaccountforstate-dependenteffectsofmonetarypolicyoneconomicactivity(

TenreyroandThwaites,

2016)

.7

Theeuro-areacontrolsinclude12lagsofinflation,theunemploymentrate,andthespreadbetweenthefive-yearBBB-ratedbondyieldandthefive-yearGermangovernmentbondyield.

Weestimatethetransmissionofmonetarypolicytomeasuresofeconomicactivityandinflationunconditionallyandconditionalontheexantestockofexcesssavings.Specifically,weestimatethefollowinglocalprojections(

Jord`a,

2005

)atamonthlyfrequencyforaseriesofhorizonsh:

Yit+h−Yit−1=β+βε+β(ExcessSavingsStockit−1)×ε+γhZit−1+eit+h,(3)

whereYitisthemeasureofeconomicactivityandinflation.

Whilewefocusontheunemploymentrateasameasureofeconomicactivity,Appendix

B

documentsthatourresultsarerobusttousingbothaggregateconsumptionandindus-trialproductioninstead.Inaddition,wealsoshowthatourresultsarerobusttocontrollingfortheCOVIDperiodaswellasbankbalancesheetstrength,respectively.

7WeconvertGDPfromaquarterlyfrequencytoamonthlyfrequencybyassigningthevalueofrealizedGDPinagivenquartertoeverymonthofthatquarter.

8

Figure3

EffectofaContractionaryMonetaryPolicyShockonEuro-AreaUnemploymentRate

(a)AverageEffect(b)DampeningEffect

Note:Figure

3

depictstheresponseoftheunemploymentratetoamonetarypolicyshocknormalizedto

increase2-yearratesby50basispoints.Panel

3a

plotstheunconditionaleffect,β,fromlocalprojections

(3),whilePanel

3b

plotstheeffectconditionalonthelevelofexcesssavings,β.Theshadedareareflects

the68percentand90percentconfidenceintervalsusingstandarderrorsfrom

DriscollandKraay

(1998)

.

3.2ExcessSavingsDampenMonetaryPolicyEffectsonActivity

Usingtheunemploymentrateasameasureofeconomicactivity,wefindthateuro-areamonetarypolicyshocksincreasetheunemploymentratebutlesssowhenexcesssavingsarehigh.Figure

3a

plotstheunconditionaleffectsofmonetarypolicyshocks,withtheunemploymentraterisingovertime,reachingitspeakeffectafter15to20months,and

increasingby30basispoints.Figure

3b

plotstheestimateofβ,whichcapturesthenon-

linearityinmonetarytransmissionwithrespecttoexcesssavings.Moreprecisely,whenthestockofexcesssavingsofaeuro-areaeconomyincreasesbyonepercentagepointofGDPrelativetothehistoricalaverage,wefindthattheeffectofthemonetarypolicyshockontheunemploymentrateisdampenedbyroughlyone-half.Overall,ourestimatedeffectsofmonetarypolicyshocksoneconomicactivityarecomparableinmagnitudetothosefromotherpapers(e.g.,

BadingerandSchiman,

2023)

.

9

Figure4

EffectofaContractionaryMonetaryPolicyShockonEuro-AreaInflation

(a)AverageEffect(b)DampeningEffect

Note:Figure

4

plotstheresponseofinflationtoamonetarypolicyshocknormalizedtoincrease2-year

ratesby50basispoints.Panel

4a

plotstheunconditionaleffect,β,fromlocalprojections(

3

),whilePanel

4b

plotstheeffectconditionalonthelevelofexcesssavings,β.Theshadedareareflectsthe68percent

and90percentconfidenceintervalsusingstandarderrorsfrom

DriscollandKraay

(1998)

.

3.3ExcessSavingsDampenMonetaryPolicyEffectsonInflation

Inadditiontodampeningtheresponseofrealoutcomes,wefindevidencethatexcesssavingsalsodampentheresponseofprices.Weestimateequation(

3

)fortwelve-monthheadlineinflationandplottheresultsinFigure

4.

Theunconditionaleffect(Figure

4a

)showsthatinflationdeclinesby40basispointsinresponsetoacontractionarymonetarypolicyshock.Whenthestockofexcesssavingsofaeuro-areaeconomyisonepercentagepointofGDPrelativetoitshistoricalaverage(Figure

4b

),thedeclineininflationisdampenedbyaround10basispoints.Ourresultsareconsistentwiththeliteraturedocumentingthatusingahigh-frequencymeasurementofshockshelpstoshowthatinflationdecreasesaftercontractionarymonetarypolicyshocks(e.g.,

Ramey,

2016,

Jaroci´nskiandKaradi,

2020)

.

3.4MonetaryPolicyTransmissionPost-Pandemic

WenextquantifytheeffectoftheriseinexcesssavingsonthetransmissionofmonetarypolicyduringtheCOVID-19recovery.With12-monthheadlineinflationintheeuro-areaaggregatehavingpeakedin2022Q4andexcesssavingsstillremainingelevatedinthesame

10

Figure5

EffectofaContractionaryMonetaryPolicyShockin2023Q1

(a)Unemploymentrate(b)Inflation

Note:Figure

5

plotstheresponseoftheunemploymentrateandinflationtoamonetarypolicyshocknormalizedtoincrease2-yearratesby50basispoints.Panels

5a

and

5b

plotthetotalmonetarypolicy

effectundertwoscenarios:(i)whenexcesssavingsareequaltozero(i.e.,βfromlocalprojections(

3

))

and(ii)whenexcesssavingsaresetequaltotheir2023Q1levelbasedonanaverageofthecountriesinoursample.

period,weuseourestimatestoquantifytheeffectivenessofmonetarypolicyfromtheperspectiveofapolicymakerin2023Q1assheorhestartstoevaluatehowtightpolicywouldneedtobegoingforward.

Figure

5

showsthatexcesssavingsdampenedtheeffectsofmonetarypolicyduringtherecoveryfromthepandemic.Asabaseline,thebluelinesdepicttheaverageresponseoftheunemploymentandinflationratestoamonetarypolicyshockundertheassumptionthatexcesssavingsareattheirhistoricalaverages(thesameasinFigures

3a

and

4a,

respectively).Thesolidblacklinesreflecttheresponseoftheunemploymentandinflationratestoamonetarypolicyshockundertheassumptionthatexcesssavingsareattheir2023Q1levels.Comparingthetwosetsofresponses,weestimatepeak-dampeningeffectsofaboutone-fourthtoone-halfontheefficacyofmonetarypolicyforboththeunemploymentandinflationrates.

11

4ExcessSavingsinaSimpleNewKeynesianModel

Inthissection,webuildamodelthatprovidesaninterpretationofourempiricalresults:higherexcesssavingsflattentheIScurve.OurmodelisasimpleNewKeynesianmodelwithequilibriumunemploymentduetomatchingfrictionsinthelabormarket.Workersfaceidiosyncratic,countercyclicalunemploymentriskagainstwhichtheycanonlybepartiallyinsuredbysavingwhileemployed.Whenunemploymentriskrises,householdswanttocutconsumptiontodaytosavemore,whichthenamplifiestheresponseoftheeconomytotheinitialshock.However,highersavingsdampenthisamplificationbyallowingforbetterrisksharing.Ourexactset-upisasimplifiedversionofthemodelin

Challeetal.

(

2017

)andissimilarto,forexample,

RavnandSterk

(

2017

)and

HeathcoteandPerri

(

2018

).Thesameforcescanalsobefoundinlessstylizedmodelsofprecautionarysavingsoverthebusinesscyclelike

Gornemannetal.

(2016),

DenHaanetal.

(

2018

),and

Cho

(

2023

).

4.1Timeline

Theeconomyispopulatedbyaunitmassofidenticalfamilies.Eachfamilyitselfconsistsofaunitmassofworkers.Atthebeginningoftheperiod,thefamilyredistributesbondsbetweenitsmemberswhowereemployedlastperiod.Unemployedmembersofthefamilyalsomightholdsomebondsordebt,dependingontheirhistory.Importantly,theyarenotabletoshareinthewealthofthefamilyuntiltheyfindajob

.8

Aftertheredistributionofbondstookplace,aggregateshocksrealizeandfirmsannouncehowmanyworkerstheyplantohire.Employedworkersproduceforthefirmstheyworkforandarepaid.Unemployedworkersreceiveunemploymentbenefits.Bothgroupsthendecidehowtosplittheirincomebetweenconsumptionandsavings.Attheendoftheperiodallemployedmembersofafamilymeetandpoolresources,whicharethenre-shuffledbetweenthesefamilymembersforthenextperiod.

8Theassumptionofarepresentativefamilythatcanshareitsresourceswithinasubsetofworkersisclearlyunrealistic.Itismeanttocaptureaworldinwhichworkersself-insurethroughsavingagainstunemploymentrisk.Theassumptionthattheemployedworkersareabletopoolresources,however,stronglysimplifiestheanalysis.Thissimplificationarisesbecauseaworker’sassetpositiononlydependson

温馨提示

  • 1. 本站所有资源如无特殊说明,都需要本地电脑安装OFFICE2007和PDF阅读器。图纸软件为CAD,CAXA,PROE,UG,SolidWorks等.压缩文件请下载最新的WinRAR软件解压。
  • 2. 本站的文档不包含任何第三方提供的附件图纸等,如果需要附件,请联系上传者。文件的所有权益归上传用户所有。
  • 3. 本站RAR压缩包中若带图纸,网页内容里面会有图纸预览,若没有图纸预览就没有图纸。
  • 4. 未经权益所有人同意不得将文件中的内容挪作商业或盈利用途。
  • 5. 人人文库网仅提供信息存储空间,仅对用户上传内容的表现方式做保护处理,对用户上传分享的文档内容本身不做任何修改或编辑,并不能对任何下载内容负责。
  • 6. 下载文件中如有侵权或不适当内容,请与我们联系,我们立即纠正。
  • 7. 本站不保证下载资源的准确性、安全性和完整性, 同时也不承担用户因使用这些下载资源对自己和他人造成任何形式的伤害或损失。

评论

0/150

提交评论