版权说明:本文档由用户提供并上传,收益归属内容提供方,若内容存在侵权,请进行举报或认领
文档简介
PublicDisclosureAuthorizedPublicDisclosureAuthorized
PolicyResearchWorkingPaper10956
FadingAwayInformalitybyDevelopment
M.NazımTamkoç
WORLDBANKGROUP
DevelopmentEconomicsGlobalIndicatorsGroupOctober2024
PolicyResearchWorkingPaper10956
Abstract
Thispaperfocusesontheroleofdevelopmentininfor-malitythroughhigherwagesandexpandedproductionpossibilities.First,itusesinformal,plant-levelsurveydataacrosscountriestodocumentthatonaverage,richercoun-trieshavesmallerinformal,unregisteredplantsintermsofemployment.Thisnegativerelationshipholdsevenaftercontrollingforplant-levelcharacteristics.Then,adynamicgeneralequilibriummodelwithincompletetaxenforcementisdevelopedsuchthatformalandinformalplantscoexistinequilibrium.Themodelallowsfortwogroupsofagentsoperatingintheinformalsector:thosewithlowerabilities
thanworkers,andthosewithabilitiesfallingbetweenworkersandformalmanagers.Inthemodel,whenplantsbecomemoreproductive,someagentsoperatinginformallychoosetobeworkersandsomeofthemtransitionintoformalityduetohigherwagesandbetterproductionpos-sibilities,whichdecreasesthemeansizeofinformalplants.Thequantitativeresultsindicatethataround30percentoftheincreaseinaggregateoutputduetohigherproductivityisassociatedwitharoughlyone-quarterdeclineinthemeansizeofinformalplants.
ThispaperisaproductoftheGlobalIndicatorsGroup,DevelopmentEconomics.ItispartofalargereffortbytheWorldBanktoprovideopenaccesstoitsresearchandmakeacontributiontodevelopmentpolicydiscussionsaroundtheworld.PolicyResearchWorkingPapersarealsopostedontheWebat
/prwp
.Theauthormaybecontactedatmtamkoc@.
ThePolicyResearchWorkingPaperSeriesdisseminatesthefindingsofworkinprogresstoencouragetheexchangeofideasaboutdevelopmentissues.Anobjectiveoftheseriesistogetthefindingsoutquickly,evenifthepresentationsarelessthanfullypolished.Thepaperscarrythenamesoftheauthorsandshouldbecitedaccordingly.Thefindings,interpretations,andconclusionsexpressedinthispaperareentirelythoseoftheauthors.TheydonotnecessarilyrepresenttheviewsoftheInternationalBankforReconstructionandDevelopment/WorldBankanditsaffiliatedorganizations,orthoseoftheExecutiveDirectorsoftheWorldBankorthegovernmentstheyrepresent.
ProducedbytheResearchSupportTeam
FadingAwayInformalitybyDevelopment*
M.NazımTamkoç†
October2024
Forthelatestversion,pleaseclickhere
Keywords:Informality,EconomicDevelopment,PlantSize,Productivity
JELClassification:E23,J24,L25,O41,O33
*IwouldliketothankJuheeBae,FilipJolevski,NormanLoayza,HibretMaemir,JorgeRodriguezMeza,FurkanSarikayaandGustavoVenturafortheircommentsandsuggestions.Thefindings,interpretations,andconclusionsexpressedinthispaperareentirelythoseoftheauthors.TheydonotnecessarilyrepresenttheviewsoftheWorldBankanditsaffiliatedorganizations,orthoseoftheExecutiveDirectorsoftheWorldBankorthegovernmentstheyrepresent.
†TheWorldBank,EnterpriseAnalysisUnitE-Mail:mtamkoc@
1
1Introduction
Informality,economicactivityoutsideofformalregulationsandinstitutionalframeworks,isoftenseenasacommonfeatureofdevelopingcountries.1Theliteraturehasfocusedonreducinginformalitythroughstrengtheningenforcementofpoliciesandloweringthecostsofoperatingformally,suchastaxratesandentryfees.However,developedcountriesdon’thaveoversightofalleconomicactivities,andtheirtaxratescanbeashighasindevelopingcountries.2Thispaperarguesthathigherlevelofinformalityinpoorercountriesisnotonlytheresultofburdensomeregulationsorinadequateenforcement,butalsoabyproductofunderdevelopment.
Inrichercountrieswithbetterproductiontechnologiesandeconomicenvironments,someworkerspreferformalwageemploymentoveroperatinganinformalbusiness,aswageratesarehigher.Likewise,somemanagersoptforformalfirmregistrationandoperationbe-causetheincomepotentialinrichermarketsmakesformalitymoreprofitabledespitethecostsoftaxesandregulations.
Inthispaper,Ifocusontheincidenceofinformalityattheextensivemargin,referringtounregisteredplants.Istartbydocumentingempiricalfactsrelatedwithinformalityinthedevelopingworld.Usingplant-leveldatafromtheWorldBankInformalSectorEnterpriseSurveys(ISES),Ishowthatinformalplantsinrichercountriestendtoemployfewerwork-ersonaveragethaninformalplantsinpoorercountries.Inotherwords,theinformalmeansizedecreaseswiththelevelofdevelopment.Forexample,informalplantsinGhanahave2.3workersonaverage,whereasinPeru,informalplantsaverageonly1.4workers.ThisnegativerelationshipbetweeninformalplantsizeandGDPpercapitapersistsevenaftercontrollingforplantcharacteristicssuchasmanagers’education,experience,andgender,sectorofac-tivity,andplantage.Moreover,whilesomeinformalplantsachieveproductivitylevels,mea-suredbyvalue-addedperworker,comparabletotheirformalcounterparts,mostoperateatverylowlevels.
Toquantifytheimpactofdevelopmentoninformality,Idevelopadynamic-generalequi-libriummodelofoccupationalchoicewhereagentsareoptimallyallocatedasworkersormanagersaccordingtotheirabilitiesinthespiritofLucas(1978)’sspan-of-controlmodelbasedonPoschke(2018).Inthemodel,whileworkers’earningsareproportionaltotheirabilities,managerialearningsareincreasinginreturnstotheirabilities.Iintroduceinfor-
1SeeDeSoto(1989),andLaPorta&Shleifer(2014),Ulyssea(2020)andOhnsorge&Yu(2022)forasurveyofinformalityliterature.
2SeeFriedmanetal.(2000)forthenegativerelationshipbetweentaxratesandinformality.
2
malitybyallowingmanagerstooperateinformallytoavoidtaxationduetoincompleteen-forcement.Theyriskbeingcaughtiftheyusecapitaloveracertainthreshold,similartoDeSoto(1989)andLeal(2014).Inequilibrium,agentsatthelowerendoftheabilitydistribu-tionoperateasinformalmanagers.Agentswithabilitieshigherthanthoseofinformalman-agers,butnothighenoughtorunplants,becomeworkers.Ifenforcementlimitsortaxesarenotexcessivelylow,informalitymayalsoexistamongagentswithabilitiesexceedingthoseofworkers.Ofthesehigher-abilityagents,therelativelylessableoperateinformally,whilethemoreablerunformalplants.Informalmanagerswithabilitieslowerthanworkersarere-ferredtoasoperatinginsubsistenceinformality.Inthecasethatenforcementlimitsortaxesaresufficientlylow,allagentswithabilitieshigherthanworkersoperateintheformalsector.
Icalibratekeymodelparameterstomatchplantsizedistribution,includinginformalplantsinGhana.Themodelsuccessfullygeneratestheobservedmeanplantsizedifferencesbetweenformalandinformalsectors.Inthebenchmarkeconomy,while90.6%ofplantsareinformal,theyaccountfor34.2%ofaggregateoutput.Moreover,71.1%ofinformalplantsoperateatthesubsistenceinformalitylevel.Hence,theaverageinformalmanagerearnslessthantheaverageworker.
Motivatedbybetterbusinessenvironmentsandhigheryearsofschoolinginrichercoun-tries,developmentisintroducedintothemodelsuchthatallmanagers’productivityin-creases.Asaresult,relativelyhigher-abilityinformalplantmanagersstartoperatingformallysince,oncemoreproductive,theydemandmorelaborandcapital.Incontrast,relativelylower-abilityinformalplantmanagersswitchtobecomeworkersinthenewequilibrium,enjoyinghigherwages.Therefore,whileinformalitydecreaseswithdevelopment,theshareofsubsistenceinformalityincreasesamonginformalplants.
Quantitativelywhentheaggregateoutputincreasesbyabout29.5%duetoimprovementsinmanagers’productivity,theoverallaverageplantsizeincreasesby30%whereasthemeaninformalplantsizedeclinesbyabout26.1%.Whenthemodelisdisciplinedtoaccountfordifferencesininformalmeanplantsizeacrosscountries,itcanexplain32.8%ofincomepercapitadifferencesonaverage.Moreover,whenonlytheformalsectorbenefitsfrompropor-tionalandskill-biasedimprovementsinthemanagers’productivity,theshareofinformalplantsshrinks,andtheoverallmeansizegrowsfastercomparedtothecasewhereallman-agersbenefitfromdevelopment.Thepaperconcludesbycomparingthegainsfromformal-izationpolicies,suchasbetterenforcementandlowertaxes:whileformalizationpolicieshavethepotentialtodecreaseinformality,theirgainsarelimitedcomparedtothegainsfromhigherproductivityassociatedwithimprovingthebusinessenvironmentandimprovinged-ucationlevels.
3
BackgroundTheinformalityliteraturegrewextensivelyfollowingDeSoto(1989).First,LaPorta&Shleifer(2008)andLaPorta&Shleifer(2014)areamongtheearlieststudiesthatutilizesISEStodocumentdifferencesbetweenformalandinformalplants.Amin&Okou(2020)extendstheircomparisontoabroadersetofcountries.Icontributetothisliteraturebysystematicallyshowingthatinformalplantstendtobelargerinpoorercountries.
Second,Rauch(1991),Loayza(1996),Amaral&Quintin(2006),D’Erasmo&Boedo(2012),Leal(2014),Meghiretal.(2015),Ulyssea(2018)andFranjoetal.(2022)developenviron-mentswhereinformalityexistsduetotheminimumwages,incompleteenforcementandfrictionsinaccessingfinance.IextendthemodelofPoschke(2018)byallowinginformalitytoexistendogenouslyduetotheincompleteenforcementoftaxes.Inthemodel,agentssortintobeingworkers,informalmanagers,andformalmanagers.Mycontributionisprovidinganenvironmentwhereagentswithabilitieslowerthanworkers(subsistenceinformality)aswellasthosewithhigherabilitiesbecomeinformalmanagers.
Third,theaboveliteraturefocusesontheformalizationpoliciessuchasreducingthecostofbeingformalortaxes,motivatedbyJohnsonetal.(1998),Fajnzylberetal.(2011),DeMeletal.(2013),Bruhn&McKenzie(2014),DeAndradeetal.(2016)andRochaetal.(2018)amongmanyothers;andincreasingenforcementasinKuehn(2014),Orsietal.(2014),Leal(2014)andUlyssea(2018).However,inthispaper,Iquantifytheroleofdevelopmentinre-ducinginformality.Loayza(2016)studieshowgrowthratesandmigrationaffectinformalityinagrowth-accountingsetup,andprojectslaborinformalityovertwodecades.Thispaperdiffersbydevelopingaspan-of-controlmodelwithheterogeneousproductionunitsanddis-cipliningthemodelusingaplantsizedistributionincludinginformality.
Lastly,thispapercontributestotheliteraturestudyingplant-levelproductivity,size,andaggregateproductivity,advancedbyHsieh&Klenow(2009),Bartelsmanetal.(2013)andHsieh&Klenow(2014).Bento&Restuccia(2017)andBento&Restuccia(2021)documentthatrichercountrieshavelargerplantsintermsofemploymentonaverage.Restuccia&Rogerson(2008),Guneretal.(2008),Garcia-Santana&Pijoan-Mas(2014)andGourio&Roys(2014)havefocusedontheroleofsize-dependentdistortionsasoneofthemainreasonsforsmallerplantsinpoorercountries.Tamkoç&Ventura(2024)studytimetaxes–rulesandregulationsthatdistortmanagers’productivetime–asadeterminantofsmallerplantsinpoorercountries,onaverage.Inthispaper,Istudytheprevalenceoflargerinformalplantsinunderdevelopedcountriesasonereasonforthesmalleroverallmeanplantsizeinthesecountries.
4
2Data
ThemaindatasourceofthispaperistheWorldBank’sISESwhichconsistsofface-to-faceinterviewswithownersormanagersofinformalplants.3Itusesanarea-basedsamplingmethodologythatgeneratesaprobabilisticsampleofinformalfirmswhereinterviewersenu-merateallplantsinarandomlyselecteduniformblocksinagivenregionorcitytodetermineregistrationstatus.Ifaplantisnotregisteredinthelocalregistrationinstitution,itiscon-sideredinformal.Withinselectedinformalplantsarerandomlyselectedinrealtimeforadeeperinterview.Varioustopicssuchasworkforce,sales,sectorandbackgroundofman-agersarecoveredinthequestionnaire.4ISESincludes25,995plant-levelobservationsfrom78regions/citiesin26countriessince2008.5ThePPPadjustedrealGDPpercapita,RGDP,andemploymentdatacomefromWorldDevelopmentIndicators(WDI).Thesamplecoverscountriesatdifferentlevelsofdevelopment:therichestcountryinthesampleisArgentinawhereasDemocraticRepublicoftheCongohasthelowestRGDPpercapitacomparedtoothercountriesinthesample.
Thenumberofworkersinaninformalplantisthetotalnumberofpaidandunpaidwork-ers.Figure1presentsthemainmotivatingfactofthepaper:richercountriestendtohavesmallerinformalplantsonaverage.Inthefigure,eachdotrepresentsacountry.They-axisandx-axisaretheaveragenumberofworkersininformalplantsandtheRGDPpercapitaineachcountryrespectively.Forexample,theaverageinformalplantinArgentinahas1.6workers,whileinGhanaandNepal,theaveragesare2.3and4.1workersperinformalplant,respectively.
ThesolidlineinFigure1isthesimplelinearregressionlinewherethelog-informalmeansizeisregressedonthelog-RGDPpercapitawhereobservationsareweightedaccordingtotheiremploymentsize.Despitethesmallsamplesize,theelasticityoftheinformalmeansizewithrespecttoRGDPpercapitaisnegativeandstatisticallysignificant.ItimpliesthatdoublingRGDPpercapitaisassociatedwith29.3%declineininformalmeansize.
ThefollowingregressionequationisestimatedtotestwhetherthenegativerelationshipbetweentheinformalmeansizeandtheRGDPpercapitapersistsaftercontrollingforplant
3Forplant-leveldatasetsandfurtherinformationaboutthemethodology,pleasevisit
4After2015,ISESusesanadaptiveclustersamplingmethodologywhichenablesthecomputationoftheprobabilityofselectionofaplantwithinablock,thusallowingtheuseofsamplingweightstomakeinferencestothepopulationofinformalbusinesseswiththeregion/city.SeeAgaetal.(2023)andAberraetal.(2022).
5PleaseseeAppendixBforthelistofcountriesandthenumberofobservations.
5
characteristics.
log¡Sizei,c¢=β0+β1log(RGDPc)+Xi,c+ϵi,c(1)
whereSizei,cisthenumberofworkersinplantiincountrycandRGDPcistheRGDPpercapitaincountryc.Xi,cincludesplantcharacteristicvariablesinplantiincountryc.Itconsistsofamanufacturingdummy;aneducationofamanagerdummywhichis1ifthehighestlevelofamanagerisatleastsecondaryschool;experienceofamanagerinthesector(inyears);afemaledummywhichtakesvalue1ifthemanagerisfemale;andtheageoftheplant(inyears,asofthedateofinterview).
Table1presentstheestimatedcoefficientsoftheEquation(1).Theelasticityoftheinfor-malmeansizewithrespecttoRGDPpercapitais-0.16andsignificantevenaftercontrollingforallplantcharacteristics.Inaddition,theestimationresultsindicatethatinformalplantsoperatinginthemanufacturingsectorsignificantlyemploymoreworkersthanthoseoper-atingintheservicessectoronaverage.Moreover,theexperienceandeducationofmanagersispositivelycorrelatedwiththesizeofinformalplants.Ontheotherhand,plantsmanagedbyafemalemanageraresignificantlysmallercomparedtoplantsmanagedbyamale.
Next,Icompareinformalplantsvis-a-visformalplantsinGhana.6WorldBankEnterpriseSurveys(WBES)conductedtwoothersurveysinGhanain2013alongwithISES:Micro-WBESandWBES.Onlyformal(registered)plantsarecoveredinbothsurveys.Micro-WBESinter-viewsplantswithfewerthan5workers,whileWBESinterviewsplantswithatleast5workers.IrefertoplantsinbothMicro-WBESandWBESasformalplants.
Table2presentsthecomparisonofinformalandformalplantsinGhana.Themeansizeofinformalplantsissmallerthanformalplants:thereare2.3workersininformalplantswhereas3and34.7workersareinvolvedinproductionintheMicro-WBESandWBESre-spectively.7Moreover,informalmanagershavelessexperienceinthesectortheyoperateincomparedtoformalmanagers.While42.8%ofinformalmanagershaveatleastasecondaryschooldegree,around65%ofworkersinformalplantshaveatleastasecondaryschoolde-gree.Tosumup,onaverage,informalplantsaresmallerandyoungercomparedtoformalplants;theirmanagershavefewerexperienceandlesseducation;thefractionoffemaleman-agersishigheramonginformalplants.
6SimilaranalysisisdonebyLaPorta&Shleifer(2014)acrossafewcountriesusingthesamedataset,andMeghiretal.(2015)andUlyssea(2018)inBrazil.
7AsSection4discussesindetail,theGhanaStatisticalService’sIntegratedBusinessEstablishmentSurveyreportsthemeansizeofinformalplantsas2.3workersandthemeansizeofformalplantsas33.8.SimilarmeansizesoftheWorldBank’splantlevelsurveydatasetswiththatoftheGhanaStatisticalService’scensusbuildconfidenceintheusageofISESandWBEStocompareinformalandformalplantsinGhana.
6
Finally,IfocusonproductivitydifferencesbetweeninformalandformalplantsinGhana.8Figure2plotsthedistributionofLog-VAperworkerinISES,Micro-WBESandWBES.Therearethreeobservationsrelatedwiththeproductivitydifferencesbetweeninformalandformalplants.First,asTable2alsoshows,informalplantsarelessproductivecomparedtoformalplants.Secondly,whilemostproductiveinformalplantsaresimilartomostunproductiveformalplantsintermsofproductivitylevels,therearesomeinformalplantsthatoperateatverylowlevels.Third,informalplantshavelongleft-tailproductivitywhereasformalplantshavelongright-tailproductivity.
3Model
ThemodelisbasedonPoschke(2018).Theinnovationinthispaperisthatmanagerscanoperateintheinformalsectortoavoiddistortions.
3.1Environment
Thereisahouseholdwithacontinuumofhouseholdmembers.Eachhouseholdmemberisbornwithaunitofefficiency,zandaunitoftimesuppliedinelastically.TheunitofefficiencyisdistributedaccordingtoacdfG(z)over[0,]andisreferredasabilityinthispaper.Thehouseholdhasapreferenceoveraconsumptiongoodanddiscountsthefutureattherate
β<1:
∞
βtlog(2)
Ateachperiod,householdmembersareassignedtobeworkersormanagersbasedontheirabilities.Workerssupplytheirabilitytocollectwages.Managersrunplantstoproducethesinglefinalgoodoftheeconomybyhiringworkersandrentingcapital.Productionofthefinalgoodrequiresrunningdifferentiatedactivitiesi.e.,usingintermediategoods.FollowingPoschke(2018),thenumberofactivitiesthatamanagerwithabilityzcanperform,M(z),
equalstozwhere>1representstheaggregatetechnologylevel.Irefertothenumber
ofactivitiesamanagercanperformasproductivitythroughoutthepaper.
8Productivityismeasuredbythelogofvalueadded(Log-VA)perworkerandVAisdefinedassalesminusexpendituresonrawmaterialsandenergyfollowingLaPorta&Shleifer(2008).
7
Thefinaloutputofaplant,y,withamanagerofabilityzcanbedefinedasfollows:
wherejdenotesdifferentactivities,njandkjaretheamountofabilityandcapitalusedinactivityjrespectively,1>α>0istheimportanceoflaborinproduction,1>γ>0isthespan-of-controlparameterandσ>1istheelasticityofsubstitutionbetweendifferentiatedproducts.
Governmentcollectstaxesfromoutputattherateτ.EnforcementoftaxcollectionisincompleteinthesensethatmanagerscanoperateinformallytoavoidtaxesinlinewithLeal(2014).However,thereisapossibilitythataninformalmanagercangetcaughtwithprobability,p(kj):
whereBrepresentstheenforcementlevelsuchthatifamanagerusesmorecapitalthanBintheproductionofthefinalgood,shewillbecaught.Therefore,managerscanavoidtaxesbylimitingtheircapitaltolessthanorequaltoBintotal.Ifamanageriscaughtwhileoperatinginformally,shelosesallprofits.
ProblemofanInformalManagerAmanagerwithabilityzwhooperatesinformallychoosestheamountofcapitalandlabortomaximizeherprofit,πI(z):
whereWandRarewagesandrentalrateofcapitalrespectively.
ProblemofaFormalManagerAmanagerwithabilityzwhooperatesformallychoosestheamountofcapitalandlabortomaximizeherprofit,πF(z).Sincethemanageroperatesformally,itsoutputissubjecttoatax,τ.
8
Thegovernmentcollectstaxesfromformalmanagersandreturnsthemtothehouseholdasalump-sumtransfereveryperiod:
Tt=Gt∀t(7)
whereTtdenotesthetransferstothehouseholdandGtisthegovernmentrevenuefromtaxation.
ProblemoftheHouseholdThehouseholdassignsitsmemberstothreeoccupations:work-ers,informalmanagersandformalmanagers,andchoosesitsconsumption,Ctandhowmuchcapitaltocarryouttothenextperiod,Kt+1inordertomaximizeitslife-timeutility:
s.t.
Ct+Kt+1=It(SW,t,SI,t,SF,t,Wt,Rt)+(1−δ+Rt)Kt+Tt
whereSW,t,SI,t,SF,tdenotethesetofworkers,informalmanagersandformalmanagersre-spectively,δisthedepreciationrateofthecapital,TtisthetransferfromgovernmentandIt(SW,t,SI,t,SF,t,Wt,Rt)isthetotalincomeofhouseholdmembers:
wherethefirstitemoftheright-handsideisthewageincomeofworkersandthesecondandthethirditemsrepresentthetotalprofitoftheinformalandformalmanagersrespectively.9
3.2PropertiesoftheEquilibrium
Thissectionfocusesonastationaryequilibriumanddiscussesitskeyfeatures.Profitofaformalmanagerwithabilityz,πF(z),canbewrittenasafunctionofparametersandinputpricesusingequations(A.3)and(A.4):
9AppendixAprovidesthefirst-orderconditionsofmanagers’problemsandthedefinitionofequilibrium.
9
AllinformalmanagerslimittheircapitalusagetoBorlessintheirplants,astheywouldbecaughtoperatinginformallyotherwise.Then,theprofitofaninformalmanagerwithabilityz,πI(z),canbewrittenasafunctionofparametersusingequations(A.5),(A.6),(A.7)and(A.8):
(11)
Iassumethatγ>>αsuchthatprofitfunctionsofbothtypesofmanagersarein-creasingandconvexinz.Thisassumptionalsoguaranteestheexistenceanduniquenessoftheequilibriumwhereinformalandformalmanagerscoexist(givenhighτandB).Ifthe
totalamountofcapitalusedinaninformalplantislessthanB,theπIisstrictlygreaterthan
πFdueto<1.ThehighestamountofcapitalthataninformalmanageruseisB.IrefertoinformalmanagerswhouseexactlyBamountofcapitalasconstrainedinformalmanagers.Theycanstillincreasetheirprofitbyhiringmorelaborgiventheirconstrainedcapital.Asaresult,theslopeofinformalmanagers’profit,πI(z),isaffected.Whentheop-timalamountofcapitalforaninformalmanagerisequaltoB,theslopeoftheinformalmanager’sprofitwithrespecttozbecomessmallerthanthatoftheformalmanager’sprofitfunction.Then,πIcancrossπFatmostoncebecausebothfunctionsarestrictlyincreasing.Sinceworkers’earningsincreaseproportionaltotheirability,thisestablishestheexistenceanduniqueness.
Figure3describesanequilibriumassignmentofhouseholdmemberstodifferentoc-cupations.Thehorizontalaxisrepresentsabilitiesandtheverticalaxisistheearningsofhouseholdmembers.WhileπI(z),thesolidline,andπF(z),thedash-dottedline,areincreas-ingandconvexwheretheycrosseachotheronlyonce,theearningsofworkers,thedashedline,islinearandincreasingwithaslopeofW.Householdmemberswithz∈[0,z)andz∈[z,z)becomeinformalmanagers,householdmemberswithabilityz∈[z,]becomeformalmanagersandremaininghouseholdmemberswithabilityz∈[z,z)assignedtobeworkersinthisequilibrium.Thesubsistenceinformalityexistswherez∈[0,z).Iftaxesarelowortheenforcementisstricter(i.e.lowB)inaneconomy,theremaybeonlysubsistenceinformalityintheequilibrium.Inotherwords,z,theabilitylevelwheretheinformalprofitfunctioncrossestheformalprofitfunction,canbesmallerthanz,thethresholdlevelwheretheearningslineofworkerscrossestheprofitofmanagersfromabove.
Thesolutiontothemanagers’probleminAppendixAshowsthattheamountofcapital
10
andlabordevotedtoeachactivityisthesameacrossactivitiesforagivenmanager.There-fore,Iexpressthecapital-laborratioattheactivitylevelwithoutlossofgenerality.Usingequations(A.3)and(A.4),thecapital-laborratioofformalmanagerscanbewrittenasfol-lows:
(12)
Similarly,thecapital-laborratioofinformalmanagerscanalsobederivedusingequations(A.5),(A.6),(A.7)and(A.8)asfollows:
Noticethatcapital-laborratiosofformalandinformalmanagersareconstantandequaltoeachotherifinformalmanagersoptimallychooselesscapitalthanB.However,moreable,constrained,informalmanagershaveasmallercapital-laborratiocomparedtoothermanagersandtheratiodecreaseswiththeabilityofinformalmanagersasγ>.
Sincemanagershireefficiencyunits,IdefinethesizeofaplantrelativetotheaverageabilityofworkersasinPoschke(2018).LetFPbethefractionofplants,i.e.thefractionofmanagers,whichisthesumofthefractionofformalmanagers,FF,andinformalmanagers,FI.Hence,themeansizeofinformalplantscanbedefinedastheratiooftheaverageabilitydemandedininformalplantsandtheaverageabilityofworkersininformalplants.Usingthemarketclearingcondition,itcanbewrittenasfollows
whereFWIistheshareofinformalworkersamongworkerssuchthatFWI(1−
温馨提示
- 1. 本站所有资源如无特殊说明,都需要本地电脑安装OFFICE2007和PDF阅读器。图纸软件为CAD,CAXA,PROE,UG,SolidWorks等.压缩文件请下载最新的WinRAR软件解压。
- 2. 本站的文档不包含任何第三方提供的附件图纸等,如果需要附件,请联系上传者。文件的所有权益归上传用户所有。
- 3. 本站RAR压缩包中若带图纸,网页内容里面会有图纸预览,若没有图纸预览就没有图纸。
- 4. 未经权益所有人同意不得将文件中的内容挪作商业或盈利用途。
- 5. 人人文库网仅提供信息存储空间,仅对用户上传内容的表现方式做保护处理,对用户上传分享的文档内容本身不做任何修改或编辑,并不能对任何下载内容负责。
- 6. 下载文件中如有侵权或不适当内容,请与我们联系,我们立即纠正。
- 7. 本站不保证下载资源的准确性、安全性和完整性, 同时也不承担用户因使用这些下载资源对自己和他人造成任何形式的伤害或损失。
最新文档
- 二零二五版苗木种植与农业综合开发合同样本4篇
- 二零二五年度教育培训股东股权转让与合作办学合同2篇
- 二零二五版婴幼儿奶粉国际市场拓展与出口合同4篇
- 2025版绿色环保型商品房预售买卖合同3篇
- 2025年度校服品牌授权与校园形象塑造合同3篇
- 2025年度事业单位合同工劳动法执行监督评估合同3篇
- 2025年度生鲜配送冷链物流承包合同范本3篇
- 2025年度个人佣金提成与长期激励合同2篇
- 课题申报参考:能源数据要素赋能可再生能源电力生产的机制与对策研究
- 课题申报参考:民族传统体育与体育非物质文化遗产的传承与保护研究
- 2025年N1叉车司机考试试题(附答案)
- 《医院财务分析报告》课件
- 2025老年公寓合同管理制度
- 2024-2025学年人教版数学六年级上册 期末综合卷(含答案)
- 2024中国汽车后市场年度发展报告
- 感染性腹泻的护理查房
- 天津市部分区2023-2024学年高二上学期期末考试 物理 含解析
- 《人工智能基础》全套英语教学课件(共7章)
- GB/T 35613-2024绿色产品评价纸和纸制品
- 2022-2023学年五年级数学春季开学摸底考(四)苏教版
- 【蚂蚁保】2024中国商业医疗险发展研究蓝皮书
评论
0/150
提交评论