版权说明:本文档由用户提供并上传,收益归属内容提供方,若内容存在侵权,请进行举报或认领
文档简介
adePolicyImplicationsiffsandImportMarketAdamJakubik,AlexanderKeckandRobertaPiermartiniWP/23/5Thisisaworkingpaper,andhenceitrepresentsresearchinprogress.ThisresearchpaperisnotmeanttorepresentthepositionsoropinionsoftheIMF,itsExecutiveBoard,IMFmanagement,theWTO,orWTOMembers,northeofficialpositionofanyWTOstaff,andiswithoutprejudicetoMembers'rightsandobligationsundertheWTO.Anyerrorsareunintentionalandourown.2023©2023InternationalMonetaryFundWP/23/5IMFWorkingPaperStrategy,PolicyandReviewDepartmentTradePolicyImplicationsofaChangingWorld:TariffsandImportMarketPowerPreparedbyAdamJakubik,AlexanderKeck,andRobertaPiermartiniAuthorizedfordistributionbyMartinSommerJanuary2023Thisisaworkingpaper,andhenceitrepresentsresearchinprogress.ThisresearchpaperisnotmeanttorepresentthepositionsoropinionsoftheIMF,itsExecutiveBoard,IMFmanagement,theWTO,orWTOMembers,northeofficialpositionofanyWTOstaff,andiswithoutprejudicetoMembers'rightsandobligationsundertheWTO.Anyerrorsareunintentionalandourown.ABSTRACT:Economictheorysuggeststhatcountries’tariffcommitmentsintradeagreementsreflecttheirimportmarketpoweratthetimeofnegotiations.However,ascountriesgrow,theirmarketpowerindifferentsectorscanchangeinunforeseenwaysandtheircommitmentsmaynolongerreflectchangedeconomicconditions.Usinganewlybuiltdatasetofpre-UruguayRoundappliedtariffsandrelyingonthetheoreticalframeworkoftheterms-of-trademotivefortradeagreements,weestimatehypotheticaltariffcommitmentsundercurrentlevelsofmarketpowerandcomparethemwithactualtariffcommitments.Wefindthatlowertariffcommitmentsrequiredtoreflectcurrenteconomicconditionswouldamounttoareductioninannualtariffcostsofupto$26.4billion–equivalenttonearly10%ofglobaltariffcosts.Ourresultsrevealsubstantialheterogeneitybetweencountriesandsectors.Thesectorswiththelargestpotentialtariffcostreductionsarevehicles(HS87)andmachineryandappliances(HS84-85).Product-leveltariffreductionswouldrangefrom0to18.5percentagepointsandareonaveragelargestforChina.Inthepast,theGATT/WTOsystemhasupdatedtariffcommitmentsthroughperiodicroundsofnegotiations,andourfindingssupporttherevivaloftheWTO'snegotiationfunctioninthisarea.JELClassificationNumbers:F11;F13;F53Keywords:tradeagreements;tradepolicy;termsoftradeAuthor’sE-MailAddress:ajakubik@,alexander.keck@,roberta.piermartini@WORKINGPAPERSOLICYIMPLICATIONSOFACHANGINGWORLD:TARIFFSANDIMPORTMARKETPOWERPreparedbyAdamJakubik,AlexanderKeck,andRobertaPiermartiniIMFWORKINGPAPERSTRADEPOLICYIMPLICATIONSOFACHANGINGWORLD:TARIFFSANDIMPORTMARKETIMFWORKINGPAPERSINTERNATIONALMONETARYFUND2ContentsIntroduction 3LiteratureReview 5DataandEmpiricalStrategy 6EstimationResults 8CounterfactualExercise 10ConcludingRemarks 12References 13AppendixA 15AppendixB 16INTERNATIONALMONETARYFUND3IntroductionThemainmotivationforcountriestojointheWTOistheirconvictionthatWTOmembershipwillincreasetrade,helptheireconomicdevelopmentandfostereconomicgrowth.TheWTOwascreatedin1995basedontermsnegotiatedbetween128originalmembers.Subsequently,36newmembershaveaccededunderindividualtermsandconditionsnegotiatedwithexistingmembers.Countries'importmarketpowerhasbeenshowntobeakeydeterminantofthesetermsandconditions(BagwellandStaiger,2011;Beshkar,Bond,andRho,2015;BeshkarandLee,2022).WhileGATT-WTOroundsofnegotiationareseeminglystatic,theworldisdynamic.Ascountriesdevelop,theirshareofworldtradeindifferentproductswillinevitablychange,andsowilltheirabilitytoaffectworldprices.Thiswouldimplythatrecurringroundsoftradenegotiationswouldbehelpfultomaintaincommitmentsatmutuallyacceptablelevelsorthatcommitmentsbeconditionedonsomemeasureofimportmarketpower.Toourknowledge,wearethefirsttomakethispointintheeconomicpolicyliterature,whichhasimportantimplicationsforhowmultilateralroundsorcommitmentsshouldbedesigned,andfromatheoreticalperspective,howthesenegotiationsshouldbemodelled.RelyingonamodelbyBagwellandStaiger(2011)–arguablythemostrigoroustheoreticalframeworkexplainingcountries'participationininternationaltradeagreements–weprovidenovelestimatesontheextenttowhichimportmarketpowerhasinfluencedtariffcommitmentsforasetoforiginalandaccededWTOmembers.Wemakeuseofanewdatasetofpre-UruguayRoundappliedtariffsinadditiontostandarddatasources.Basedontheseestimates,wepredictthecommitmentsthatmighthavebeennegotiatedundercurrentlevelsofmarketpower.Weestimatethattariffcutsrequiredtoreflectcurrenteconomicconditionswouldamounttoareductioninannualtariffcostsofupto$26.4billion.Ourresultsrevealsubstantialheterogeneitybetweencountriesandsectors.Thesectorswiththelargestpotentialtariffcostreductionsarevehicles(HS87)andmachineryandappliances(HS84-85).Product-levelreductionswouldrangefrom0to18.5percentagepoints,withChinafeaturingthelargestaveragereductions.Giventhestrongsupportintheliteraturefortheimportanceofimportmarketpowerindeterminingtariffbindings,wefurtherarguethatcontinuousroundsoftradenegotiationsarenecessaryowingtoshiftsinmarketpowerovertimethat,inpart,maybeendogenouslydeterminedbyearlierroundsofliberalisation.Openinguptotradechangesacountry'spatternofspecialisationandopensuppotentialforstructuraltransformationatapaceandmannerwhichareoftendifficulttopredict.Thisimpliesthatterms-of-tradeexternalitiescanariseinproductswheretariffswereinitiallysetatacooperativelevel.ManycountrieshavebenefittedgreatlyfromexpandedmarketaccessopportunitiesafterjoiningtheWTOandtheirrapideconomicgrowthanddevelopmenthasexceededexpectations(TangandWei,2009;Larchet.al,2019).Astheyhavedeveloped,theirimportmarketpowerhasincreasedforcertainproducts,whiledomesticproductionexpandedforothers.Givenmembers'evolutionofmarketpower,existingcommitmentsmayceasetoadequatelyreflectpotentialterms-of-tradeexternalities.Absentfurtheradjustments,tradetensionsandpolicyuncertaintymayincrease,reflectinggrowingincentivesbyallcountriestodeviatefromthecooperativeequilibrium.Thosewithincreasedmarketpowermaywishtoraisetariffstoenjoygreaterterms-of-tradeimprovements,althoughinpracticethisismitigatedbyrelativelyhighexistingtariffs;therestmaywishtousehighertariffsasleverageinnegotiations.SomeobservershaveviewedtheTrumpadministration’sunilateraltariffincreasesin2018asbargainingtariffs,withthegoalofinducingtradingpartnerstoreducetheirtariffs(MattooandStaiger,2020;Sheldon,2022).Interestingly,ourestimatedreductioninUStradingpartners’INTERNATIONALMONETARYFUND4annualtariffrevenuenecessarytoneutralizeterms-of-tradeexternalitiesisofcomparablemagnitudetoUSannualtariffrevenueincreasesbetween2018and2019.TheGATT/WTOsystemhasusuallyaddressedsuchsituations(andthepossiblebuild-upoftradetensions)throughperiodic"rounds"ofnegotiationsseekingtoreflectnewmarketrealities(BaldwinandRobert-Nicoud,2015).SevenroundspriortotheUruguayRoundprincipallyinvolvedlike-mindeddevelopedcountriesandhadastheirobjectivetosubstantiallyreducetariffsandtoeliminatepreferences(WTO,2007).Table1showstheresultingincrementaltariffreductions.Theseroundsofnegotiationshavehelpedtorebalancecommitments.However,nonewroundshavebeenconcludedsince1995.TheWTOhasaddedmembersthroughtherigorousArticleXIIaccessionsprocess,creatingpossibleasymmetriesbetweenthetariffsofthesenewmembersandthosethatjoinedbefore(SubramanianandWei,2007;TangandWei,2009).Atthesametime,thelasttwodecadeshavewitnessedsignificantandunforeseenchangesinthesharesofworldtradeacrosscountries.ThispaperprovidesfurtherempiricalsupportforthecontinuingimportanceoftheWTO'snegotiatingfunctioninlightofrecentdevelopments.Table1:PastroundsoftariffreductionsGATTWTOyearsoftariffreductionsMFNtariffreductionofindustrialcountriesforindustrialproducts(excl.petroleum))mentationioddcoveredtarifftiononMFNmportsyearenevaAnnecy49)Torquay1950-51)Geneva6)lonRoundnnedyRoundTokyoRound1973-79)guayRoundNoteTariffreductionsforthefirstfiveroundsrefertotheUnitedStatesonly.ThecalculationofaverageratesofreductionsareweightedbyMFNimportvalues.Source:WTO(2007).Therestofthepaperisorganisedasfollows:Section2reviewstherelevantliterature,Section3describesthedata,includinganew,unpublisheddatabaseonappliedtariffsbeforetheconclusionoftheUruguayRound.Wealsoprovidedescriptivestatisticsofthemainvariablesusedintheregressionanalysis.InSection4,wepresentourempiricalmodelandestimationresults.Section5presentstheresultsofourcounterfactualexerciseonwhattariffbindingsmighthavelookedlikeunderpresentdaymarketpowerconditions.Section6concludes.IMFWORKINGPAPERSTRADEPOLICYIMPLICATIONSOFACHANGINGWORLD:TARIFFSANDIMPORTMARKETIMFWORKINGPAPERSINTERNATIONALMONETARYFUND5LiteratureReviewWhyisimportmarketpowerimportantfortradepolicy?AsWTOmembersgrowtheireconomies,theymaybecomesignificantbuyersofcertainproductsontheworldmarketandabletoinfluencetheworldprice.Thiscreatesanincentivetousetradepolicytotakeadvantageofpotentialterms-of-tradegains(Johnson,1953;GrossmanandHelpman,1995;BagwellandStaiger,1990,2002,2010,2011).Alargeenoughimportingcountrymayapplytariffstodrivedowntheworldpricenetoftariffs,astheburdenoftradetaxesissharedbetweentheconsumersintheimportingcountryandtheproducersinexportingcountries.Thiscanbenefitthecountryimposingthetariffattheexpenseofexportingcountries,asitisabletoimportmoreforthesameamountofexports.Inotherwords,itstariffactionhasanegativeexternalityonitstradingpartners'terms-of-trade.However,ifallcountriesactedonthisimpulse,terms-of-tradegainswouldcanceleachotherout,leavingeveryoneworseoff,withhighertariffsandlessoveralltrade.Itfollowsthatcooperationtoescapethisprisoner’sdilemma,intheshapeoftradeagreements,ismutuallybeneficial.Indeed,BagwellandStaiger(2002,2010)arguethisistheprincipalpurposeoftradeagreements:theydefineacooperativeequilibriumwheremutuallyagreedmaximumor"bound"tarifflevelsacttointernaliseterms-of-tradeexternalities.1OnemightthenaskwhydoGATT/WTOnegotiationsplacetheemphasisonmarketaccessratherthanterms-of-trade.Bagwell,Mavroidis,andStaiger(2002)pointoutthenegativeexternalitygeneratedbyanimporttariffcanbeequivalentlyinterpretedasaterms-of-tradelossorarestrictionofmarketaccess;concernabouttheimpactofforeignmarketaccessrestrictionsonthepricereceivedbydomesticexportingfirmsisinfactconcernabouttheirterms-of-tradeeffects.Buthowexactlyisimportmarketpowerrelatedtoboundtariffs?BagwellandStaiger(2011)startbyshowingthatinasettingwithoutpoliticaleconomymotives(eventhoughnotquiterealistic),atradeagreementfullyinternalisesimportmarketpowerbasedterms-of-tradeexternalitiesandpoliticallyoptimalbindingsarezero(i.e.uncorrelatedwithmarketpower).However,whengovernmentshavepoliticaleconomymotives,theirmodelimpliesthatthereductionfrompre-negotiationtarifflevelsisproportionaltopre-negotiationimportlevels,2withnew(generallynon-zero)boundlevelsbeingalsoinverselycorrelatedwiththelatterwhencontrollingfortheformer.3Theauthorsthenshowempirically,usingasampleof16accededWTOmembers,thatinlinewiththeirmodel,bindingsaredeterminedbypre-accessionimportsandtarifflevels.Otherstudieshaveconfirmedtheroleofterms-of-tradefortariffsetting.Broda,Limão,andWeinstein(2008)showthatimportersthathavemarketpoweruseitinsettingnoncooperativetradepolicy,likeinthecaseoftariffspriortoWTOorinareasnotcoveredbycooperation.Beshkar,Bond,andRho(2015)confirmforasampleof108WTOmembersthatbothoptimalbindingsandflexibility(thedifferencebetweenbindingsand1Beyondneutralisingterms-of-tradeexternalities,othereconomicrationalesfortradepolicycommitmentsininternationalagreementsincludepoliticaleconomyconsiderations,makingcrediblecommitmentsvis-à-visdomesticconstituencies,internalisingproductionrelocationandenvironmentalexternalities,andreducingtradepolicyuncertainty.2Whendemandandsupplyarenon-linear,thisbecomesamoregeneraltermcapturinginternationalcost-shiftingmotives.3Thereasoningisthatwithpoliticaleconomyfactorsatplay,governmentsfaceadditionalresistanceinreducingtariffs,andsomutuallyagreedreductionsaremoreconcentratedinsectorswheretheexternalities(duetoimportmarketpower)arelargest.INTERNATIONALMONETARYFUND6appliedtariffs)areinverselyrelatedtoimportermarketpower.4Intheirmodel,countriesnegotiateceilingbindingsabovetheirappliedtariffstoretainacertainflexibilitytoaddressshocksinaworldwithasymmetricinformationacrosscountries.DataandEmpiricalStrategyWetakedataontradeflowsfromtheUNComtradedatabase.DataonappliedtariffratesandWTObindingcommitmentsaretakenfromvariousWTOsources.5WTObindingsaretakenfromtheWTOCTSdatabaseandarebasedonmembercountries'schedulesofaccession.AppliedtariffsinforcebeforetheconclusionoftheUruguayRoundaretakenfromahithertounreleaseddatabaseavailabletous,butnotyetprocessedorincludedintheWTO'sIDBdatabase.Thesedataareavailableattarifflinelevelfor74GATTmembersforvariousyearsbetween1988and1996.AppliedtariffsinforcepriortoWTOaccessionofmembersthatjoinedaftertheUruguayRoundaretakenfromtheWTOIDBdatabase,asareappliedtariffscurrentlyinforce.DataindifferentHSversionsareconcordedusingconversiontablesfromUNStatisticsDivision.Ouranalysisisatthesix-digitHSsubheadinglevel,theclosestavailableproxyforproductmarkets.WereferthereadertoAppendixAfortheyearsusedforeachmemberinourestimationsamples.Ourfinalsample,determinedbytheavailabilityofdatafromthefourabovementioneddatabases,includes31UruguayRoundparticipantsand10subsequentaccessions,coveringallG20economiesexceptArgentina.Ourdataalsorevealssubstantialheterogeneityacrosscountriesandindustriesintermsoftheirevolutionofworldimportshares,andhenceofchangesinimportmarketpower.Whileitisreasonabletoanticipatechangesfromtradeliberalisation,theexactpathandtimingofthesechangesaredifficulttoforesee.Figure1usesemergingmarketssuchasBrazil,China,MexicoandVietNamasexamplestoillustratehowworldimportsharesmayshrinkorgrowasacountrydevelops.Forexample,asBrazil’sagriculturaloutputhasexpanded,ithasgainedsignificantmarketsharesinkeyfertilizerimports.MeanwhileChina’sshareofsoybeanimportshasrisenfromaround5%to70%injusttwodecades,notablyalsoduetoanincreaseddemandforanimalfeedasmeatconsumptionhasrisen.Likewise,VietNam’sshareofmaizeimportshasrisenfromaround0%toover6%sinceitsWTOaccession.OthersignsofChina’sdevelopmentandagrowingmiddleclassareitsshareofcarimports,whichhasrisenfromaround0%to15%anditsshareofheavyaircraftimports,upfrom5%to20%.Chinesemanufacturinghasalsogrownintechnologicalsophisticationanditsshareofindustrialrobotimportshasgrownfromaround0%toover25%.Mexico,ontheotherhand,hasbecomeincreasinglyactiveinassemblystagesofglobalvaluechains,itsshareofcomputerpartsimportsupfromunder1%toaround6%.However,asdomesticindustriesdevelop,importsharesmayshrink.Forexample,China’sshareofrailwaycoachimportshasrisenfirstfrom2.5%to15%beforeshrinkingto0%overthesameperiod,withasimilarpatternfoundforcomputersystems.4Theintuitionforthisistwofold.First,thereisademandforflexibilityintheagreementtoaccommodatepreferenceshocks,butasterms-of-tradeexternalitiesarehigherinsectorswithgreaterimportermarketpower,flexibilityentailscumulativelygreaterexternalitiesasshocksariseinthesesectors.Therefore,anoptimalagreementwillbalancethedemandforflexibilitywiththeneedtointernalisehigherexternalitiesthroughlowerbindingsinthesesectors.Second,foranygivenlevelofbindings,unilateraloptimalappliedtariffsarehigherforgreaterimportermarketpower,implyinglessflexibility.5Non-advaloremtariffsareexcludedfromthedataset.IMFWORKINGPAPERSTRADEPOLICYIMPLICATIONSOFACHANGINGWORLD:TARIFFSANDIMPORTMARKETIMFWORKINGPAPERSINTERNATIONALMONETARYFUND7Figure1:Evolutionofsharesoftotalworldimports(1995−2017)Source:Authors’calculationsbasedonUNComtradeDatabase.VerticallinedenotesWTOaccessionyear.IMFWORKINGPAPERSTRADEPOLICYIMPLICATIONSOFACHANGINGWORLD:TARIFFSANDIMPORTMARKETIMFWORKINGPAPERSINTERNATIONALMONETARYFUND8Ourbenchmarkempiricalspecificationisequivalenttoequation(15a)inBagwellandStaiger(2011)6:TTO=F0+F1Tre−wTO+F2V+6HS2(i)+入c+uic(1)InthisspecificationcrepresentsaWTOmember,iatarifflineattheHSsixdigitlevel,TTOistheWTObinding,Tre−wTOisthepre-WTOappliedtariff,Visthepre-WTOvalueofimports,6HS2(i)isanHSchapterlevelfixedeffect,入cisacountryfixedeffectanduicistheerrorterm.Theupshotofterms-of-tradetheory(seeSection2)isthepredictionthat,givenaproduct'spoliticaleconomyanddemandandsupplyslopeparameters,themagnitudeofthenegotiatedtariffreductionTre−wTO−TTOisproportionaltothepotentialforgeneratingaterms-of-tradeexternality,alsoreferredtoasinternationalcost-shiftingmotives,whichinthelinearcaseiscapturedbytheratioofpre-negotiationimportvolumetoworldprice,proxiedbyVRearrangingtermsyields(1),wherethesignofF2,ourmainparameterofinterest,isexpectedtobenegative.8ThesignofF1isexpectedtobepositiveifthepre-WTOpoliticaleconomyconsiderationsthatdeterminedTre−wTOprevail.EstimationResultsTable2presentsresultsforUruguayRoundparticipantsbyWTOdevelopmentstatusandproductcategoriesagriculture(AG)andnon-agriculturalmarketaccess(NAMA).TherationaleisthatpoliticaleconomyanddemandandsupplycharacteristicscapturedbythemodelparametersmaydifferandnegotiationsforAGandNAMAfollowedseparatetrackswithdifferentmodalitiesandobjectives.Ournovelfindingisthattheterms-of-trademotivewasasignificantdeterminantofdevelopingcountryNAMAtariffcommitmentsduringtheUruguayRound(Column6).9Wedonotfindasignificantrolefortheterms-of-trademotiveinthecaseofdevelopingcountryAGproductsorinthecaseofdevelopedeconomiesduringtheUruguayRound.Thesefindingsareconsistentwiththefactthatdevelopedcountrieshaddecreasedtheirtariffsalreadyoversevenpriorroundsofnegotiations,whiledevelopingcountriesacceptedtheirfirstmeaningfultariffbindingsintheUruguayRound–andthisonlyinNAMA,asthemainpurposeofAGnegotiationswasthe"tariffication"ofquantitativerestrictionsandnotactualtariffconstraints.SinceWTObindingscannottakevalueslessthanzero,wealsoconfirmthattheseresultsarerobusttousingTOBITestimation(seeAppendixB).Evaluatedatthesamplemeansaceterisparibusincreaseinpre-WTONAMAimportsbyonestandarddeviationispredictedtolowerboundtarifflevelsbyabout0.5%basedonthefullsampleofdevelopingcountries.However,therearelargedifferencesacrossthecountriesinthesample,rangingfrom0.0%to3.7%.6BagwellandStaiger(2011)presentresultsoftheirbenchmarkspecification(15a)inTable3A.7Seeequation(11)inBagwellandStaiger(2011).8EquivalentlyinBagwellandStaiger(2011),rearrangingequation(11)yieldsequation(12)(andequation(13)inthenon-linearcase),theparametersofwhichcanbeestimatedusingregressionequations(14a)and(14b),andversionsoftheformerwithfixed-effects,(15a)and(15b).Wefocusouranalysisonthebenchmarkspecification(15a)sinceelasticitydataisnotavailableatsufficientdisaggregationandcountry-yearcoveragetoestimate(14b)andworldpricesarenotavailableatsufficientdisaggregationtoestimate(15b).9Thiscoefficientiscomparableto-0.0044foundbyBagwellandStaiger(2011)foraccededmembers.IMFWORKINGPAPERSTRADEPOLICYIMPLICATIONSOFACHANGINGWORLD:TARIFFSANDIMPORTMARKETIMFWORKINGPAPERSINTERNATIONALMONETARYFUND9Table2:OLSregressionresultsforthesampleofcountriesparticipatingintheUruguayRound(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)DependentDevelopedDevelopedAGDevelopedNAMADevelopingAllDevelopingAGDevelopingVariable:WTObindingAllGoodsGoodsNAMAPre-WTOtariff*****Pre-WTOimport*valueConstant161**2***ObservationsR-squaredCountryFEesesesesesesSectorFEesesesesesesRobuststandarderrorsinparentheses;***denotesp<0.01,**p<0.05and*p<0.1Table3presentsresultsformembersthataccededaftertheUruguayRound.UsingasamplewithlittleoverlapwiththatofBagwellandStaiger(2011)wealsofindthattheterm-of-trademotivewasasignificantdeterminantoftheirWTOcommitments.10Inlinewiththeirresults,ourcoefficientforAGproductsisanorderofmagnitudelargerinabsolutevaluecomparedtoNAMAproducts,withaggregateresultsdrivenbythelatter.ThesefindingsarealsorobusttousingTOBITestimation(seeAppendixB).Evaluatedatthesamplemeansaceterisparibusincreaseinpre-WTOimportsbyonestandarddeviationispredictedtolowerboundtarifflevelsbyabout1.0%basedonthefullsample,5.5%forAGand0.8%forNAMA.Giventheheterogenoussample,therearelargedifferencesacrosscountries,rangingfrombelow0.1%to25.0%forAGand0.0%and2.6%forNAMA.11Whilethesequantificationsprovideausefulcomparisonofournovelfindingswiththeexistingliterature,theyconcernahypotheticalonestandarddeviationdifferenceinimports.Inthenextsection,wefocusonthepossibleimplicationsofactualobservedchangesinmarketpowerwhichexhibitsubstantialvariationacrosscountriesandsectors.10Oursampleof10accededmembersisdeterminedbytheavailabilityofpre-accessiontariffsintheWTOIDBdatabasewhicharenotifiedbyeachmember.Ourdatahasonlythreecountries(China,Nepal,andNorthMacedonia)incommonwiththe16accededmembersinBagwellandStaiger(2011),whorelyontheUNCTADTRAINSdatabasefortariffs.11InBagwellandStaiger(2011)theequivalentfigureatthefullsamplemeanis1.7%.IMFWORKINGPAPERSTRADEPOLICYIMPLICATIONSOFACHANGINGWORLD:TARIFFSANDIMPORTMARKETIMFWORKINGPAPERSINTERNATIONALMONETARYFUND10Table3:OLSregressionresultsforthesampleofcountriesthataccededtoWTOafter1995(1)(2)(3)DependentVariable:WTObindingAllProductsAGNAMAPre-WTOtariff0.455***(0.008)0.526***(0.027)0.451***(0.006)Pre-WTOimportvalue-0.001**(0.000)-0.019***(0.003)-0.001**(0.000)Constant5.023***(0.720)(0.886)3.466***(0.287)Observations41,1604,54236,618R-squared0.6760.6190.720CountryFEesesesSectorFEesesesRobuststandarderrorsinparentheses;***denotesp<0.01,**p<0.05and*p<0.1CounterfactualExerciseWesimulateacounterfactualscenariotopredictthelevelofWTObindingsthatwouldhavebeennegotiatedhadcurrentimportmarketpowerconditionsprevailedatthetimeofcreationof/entryintoWTO,usingthesampleofcountrieswhereimportmarketpowerturnedouttobeasignificantpredicto
温馨提示
- 1. 本站所有资源如无特殊说明,都需要本地电脑安装OFFICE2007和PDF阅读器。图纸软件为CAD,CAXA,PROE,UG,SolidWorks等.压缩文件请下载最新的WinRAR软件解压。
- 2. 本站的文档不包含任何第三方提供的附件图纸等,如果需要附件,请联系上传者。文件的所有权益归上传用户所有。
- 3. 本站RAR压缩包中若带图纸,网页内容里面会有图纸预览,若没有图纸预览就没有图纸。
- 4. 未经权益所有人同意不得将文件中的内容挪作商业或盈利用途。
- 5. 人人文库网仅提供信息存储空间,仅对用户上传内容的表现方式做保护处理,对用户上传分享的文档内容本身不做任何修改或编辑,并不能对任何下载内容负责。
- 6. 下载文件中如有侵权或不适当内容,请与我们联系,我们立即纠正。
- 7. 本站不保证下载资源的准确性、安全性和完整性, 同时也不承担用户因使用这些下载资源对自己和他人造成任何形式的伤害或损失。
最新文档
- 生产力透视与提升
- 2024消防工程改造与升级合同
- 梦想砌成家园
- 金融业务全景解析
- 2024深圳小微企业社保补贴申报流程优化与合同条款3篇
- 基础设施建设战略合作协议书(2篇)
- 大型展会推广合同(2篇)
- 2024年高铁站房建设土木工程承包合同范本3篇
- 2024房屋租赁合同
- 4 不做“小马虎”第二课时(说课稿 )2023-2024学年统编版道德与法治一年级下册 第一单元 我的好习惯
- 货物供应、运输、包装说明方案
- (完整版)英语高频词汇800词
- 严重精神障碍患者发病报告卡
- 《基础马来语》课程标准(高职)
- 2021年国标热镀锌钢管规格、尺寸理论重量表
- 乌鲁木齐基准地价修正体系
- DB32-T 3177-2017草莓-蕹菜水旱轮作设施栽培技术规程 -(高清现行)
- GB∕T 3216-2016 回转动力泵 水力性能验收试验 1级、2级和3级
- 七年级数学资料培优汇总精华
- IEC61850研讨交流之四-服务影射
- 材料力学压杆稳定
评论
0/150
提交评论