




已阅读5页,还剩16页未读, 继续免费阅读
版权说明:本文档由用户提供并上传,收益归属内容提供方,若内容存在侵权,请进行举报或认领
文档简介
The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance 46 (2006) 190210 Financial development and dynamic investment behavior: Evidence from panel VAR Inessa Lovea, Lea Zicchinob, a World Bank, Research DepartmentFinance Group, 1818 Hst, NW, MC3-300, Washington, DC 20433, United States b Bank of England, Monetary Instruments and Markets Division, HO-2, Threadneedle Street, London EC2R 8AH, UK Received 14 April 2004; received in revised form 31 October 2005; accepted 4 November 2005 Abstract We apply vector autoregression (VAR) to fi rm-level panel data from 36 countries to study the dynamic relationship between fi rms fi nancial conditions and investment. By using orthogonalized impulse-response functions we are able to separate the fundamental factors (such as marginal profi tability of investment) fromthefi nancialfactors(suchasavailabilityofinternalfi nance)thatinfl uencethelevelofinvestment.We fi nd that the impact of fi nancial factors on investment, which indicates the severity of fi nancing constraints, is signifi cantly larger in countries with less developed fi nancial systems. Our fi nding emphasizes the role of fi nancial development in improving capital allocation and growth. 2006 Board of Trustees of the University of Illinois. All rights reserved. Keywords: Financial development; Vector autoregression; Dynamic investment behavior 1. Introduction Unlike the neoclassical theory of investment, the literature based on asymmetric information emphasizes the role played by moral hazard and adverse selection problems in a fi rms decision to invest in physical and human capital. The presence of asymmetric information means that the classical dichotomy between real and fi nancial variables may no longer hold. Financial variables canhaveanimpactonrealvariables,suchasthelevelofinvestmentandtherealinterestrate,aswell aspropagateandamplifytheeffectsofexogenousshockstotheeconomy.Forexample,Bernanke Corresponding author. Tel.: +44 20 7601 5212; fax: +44 20 7601 3217. E-mail address: lea.zicchinobankofengland.co.uk (L. Zicchino). 1062-9769/$ see front matter 2006 Board of Trustees of the University of Illinois. All rights reserved. doi:10.1016/j.qref.2005.11.007 I. Love, L. Zicchino / The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance 46 (2006) 190210191 and Gertler (1989) show that a fi rms net worth (a fi nancial variable) can be used as collateral in order to reduce the agency cost associated with the presence of asymmetric information between lenders and borrowers. In this model, fi rms investment decisions are not only dependent on the present value of future marginal productivity of capital, as the q-theory predicts, but also on the level of collateral available to the fi rms when they enter a loan contract. Since economists started to look at real phenomena abstracting from the Arrow-Debreu framework with its frictionless capital markets, a vast literature has been developed on the rela- tionship between investment decisions and fi rms fi nancing constraints (see Hubbard, 1998, for a review). Even though asymmetric information between borrowers and lenders may be not the only source of imperfection in the credit markets, fi rms seem to prefer internal to external fi nance to fund their investments. This observation leads to the prediction of a positive relation- ship between investment and internal fi nance. The fi rst study on panel data by Fazzari, Hubbard, and Peterson (1988) fi nds that, after controlling for investment opportunities with Tobins q, changes in net worth have a greater impact on investment by fi rms with higher costs of external fi nancing. The link between the cost of external fi nancing and investment decisions not only sheds light on the dynamics of business cycles but also represents an important element in understanding economic development and growth. For instance, in the presence of moral hazard in the credit market, fi rms that need a bank loan may be induced to undertake risky investment projects with low expected marginal productivity. This corporate decision affects the growth path of the econ- omy, which may even fall into a poverty trap (see Zicchino, 2001). Rajan and Zingales (1998), Demirguc-KuntandMaksimovic(1998)andWurgler(2000),amongothers,haveinvestigatedthe link between fi nance and growth by asking whether underdeveloped legal and fi nancial systems could prevent fi rms from investing in potentially profi table growth opportunities. Their empirical results show that an active stock market, developed fi nancial intermediaries and the respect of legal norms are determinants of economic growth. Estimation of the relationship between investment and fi nancial variables is challenging because it is diffi cult for an econometrician to observe fi rms net worth and investment oppor- tunities. In theory, the measure of investment opportunities is the present value of expected future profi ts from additional capital investment, or what is commonly called marginal q. This is the shadow value of an additional unit of capital and, under certain conditions, it can be shown to be a suffi cient statistic for investment (Hayashi, 1982). In other words, it is the fundamental factor that determines investment policy of profi t-maximizing fi rms in effi cient markets. The diffi culty in measuring marginal q, which is not observable, results in low explana- tory power of the q-models and, typically, entails implausible estimates of the adjustment cost parameters.1 Another challenge is fi nding an appropriate measure for the fi nancial factors that enter the investment equation in models with capital markets imperfections. A widely used measure for the availability of internal funds is cash fl ow (current revenues less expenses and taxes, gen- erally scaled by capital). However, cash fl ow is likely to be correlated with future investment profi tability.2 This makes it diffi cult to distinguish the response of investment to the fundamen- 1 See Whited (1998) and Erickson and Whited (2000) for a discussion of the measurement errors in investment models. Also see Schiantarelli (1996) and Hubbard (1998) for a review on methodological issues related to investment models with fi nancial constraints. 2 For example, the current realization of cash fl ow would proxy for future investment opportunities if the productivity shocks were positively serially correlated. 192I. Love, L. Zicchino / The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance 46 (2006) 190210 tal factors, such as marginal profi tability of capital, and fi nancial factors, such as net worth (see Gilchrist and Himmelberg, 1995, 1998, for further discussion of this terminology). In this paper we use the vector autoregression (VAR) approach to overcome this problem and isolate the response of investment to fi nancial and fundamental factors. Specifi cally, we focus on the orthogonalized impulse-response functions, which show the response of one variable of interest (i.e. investment) to an orthogonal shock in another variable of interest (i.e. marginal productivity or a fi nancial variable). By orthogonalizing the response we are able to identify the effect of one shock at a time, while holding other shocks constant. Weusefi rm-levelpaneldatafrom36countriestostudythedynamicrelationshipbetweenfi rms fi nancial conditions and investment levels. Our main interest is to study whether the dynamics of investmentaredifferentacrosscountrieswithdifferentlevelsofdevelopmentoffi nancialmarkets. We argue that the level of fi nancial development in a country can be used as an indication of the different degrees of fi nancing constraints faced by fi rms. After controlling for the shocks to fundamental factors, we interpret the response of investment to fi nancial factors as evidence of fi nancing constraints and we expect this response to be larger in countries with lower levels of fi nancial development. To test this hypothesis we divide our data in two groups according to the degree of fi nancial development of the country in which they operate. We document signifi cant differences in the response of investment to fi nancial factors for the two groups of countries. Furthermore, splitting the sample based on different indicators of economic development does not produce signifi cant differences, supporting our claim that the level of fi nancial development is the main determinant of fi nancing constraints. We believe our paper contributes to a number of strands in the recent fi nancial economics liter- ature.Wecontributetotheliteratureonfi nancialconstraintsandinvestmentinseveralways.First, by using vector autoregressions on panel data we are able to consider the complex relationship between investment opportunities and the fi nancial situation of the fi rms, while allowing for a fi rm-specifi c unobserved heterogeneity in the levels of the variables (i.e. fi xed effects). Second, thanks to a reduced-form VAR approach, our results do not rely on strong assumptions that are necessary in models that use the q-theory of investment or Euler equations. Third, by analyzing orthogonalized impulse-response functions we are able to separate the response of investment to shocks coming from fundamental or fi nancial factors. We also contribute to the fi nance and growth literature by presenting new evidence that investment in fi rms operating in fi nancially underdeveloped countries exhibits dynamic patterns consistent with the presence of fi nancing constraints. Our paper also adds to the recent work that used dynamic panel-data techniques to arguethatthere is a casual link between fi nancial develop- ment and growth (see, for example, Beck and Levine, 2004). While most of the previous studies relied on country-level data, our paper uses fi rm-level data to demonstrate how the link between fi nance and growth operates on the level of the fi rm and to provide additional evidence on the channelsbehindthislink.Specifi cally,wefi ndthatfi nancialdevelopmenthasanimmediateeffect on effi cient allocation of capital via investment that follows the most productive uses of capital. Our fi nding is also consistent with the evidence presented by Beck, Demirguc-Kunt, Levine, and Maksimovic (2001) who found that it is easier for fi rms to access external fi nancing in countries with a higher level of overall fi nancial sector development. Our paper also adds to the recent debate on bank-based versus market-based fi nancial systems (see, for example, Demirguc-Kunt and Levine, 2001a, b, and Beck and Levine (2002), among others). This literature demonstrated that despite confl icting theoretical predictions, there is no empirical evidence of the relationship between fi nancial structures and economic growth. How- ever, the literature has found that it is the overall fi nancial development that helps in explaining I. Love, L. Zicchino / The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance 46 (2006) 190210193 cross-countries differences in economic performance. Our fi ndings are consistent with this liter- ature and expand the range of real effect previously studied to include the micro-level evidence of the effect of fi nancial development on investment behavior and capital allocation. Our paper is also related to Gilchrist and Himmelberg (1995, 1998), who were the fi rst to analyze the relationship between investment, future capital productivity and fi rms cash fl ow with a panel-data VAR approach. They use a two-stage estimation procedure to obtain measures of what they call fundamental q and fi nancial q. These factors are then substituted in a structural model of investment, which is a transformation of the Euler-equation model. Unlike Gilchrist and Himmelberg, we do not estimate a structural model of investment, but instead study the unrestricted reduced-form dynamics afforded by the VAR (which is in effect the fi rst-stage in their estimation). Gallegati and Stanca (1999) also investigate the relationship between fi rms balance sheets and investment by estimating reduced-form VARs on company panel data for UK fi rms. Despite some differences in the specifi cation of the empirical model and the estimation methodology, the approach and the results of their paper are similar to ours. However, they do not present an analysis of the impulse-response functions, which we consider to be the main tool in separating the role of fi nancial variables in companies investment decisions. In addition, the distinguishingfeatureofourpaperisthefocusonthedifferencesinthedynamicbehavioroffi rms in countries with different levels of fi nancial development. Finally, our paper is related to Love (2003) who uses the Euler-equation approach and shows that fi nancing constraints are more severe in countries with lower levels of fi nancial development, the same as we fi nd in this paper. However, the interpretation of the results in the previous paper is heavily dependent on the assumptions and parameterization of the model, while the approach we use here imposes the bare minimum of restrictions on parameters and temporal correlations among variables. The rest of the paper is as follows: Section 2 presents the empirical specifi cation and the data description; Section 3 provides the results of our work; and Section 4 presents our conclusions. 2. Empirical methodology We use a panel-data vector autoregression methodology. This technique combines the tra- ditional VAR approach, which treats all the variables in the system as endogenous, with the panel-data approach, which allows for unobserved individual heterogeneity. We specify a fi rst- order VAR model as follows: zit= 0+ 1zit1+ fi+ dc,t+ et(1) where ztis either a three-variable vector SKB, CFKB, IKB or a four-variable vector SKB, CFKB, IKB, TOBINQ; SKB, sales to capital ratio, is our proxy for the marginal productivity of capital,3IKB is the investment to capital ratio, which is our main variable of interest, CFKB is cash fl ow scaled by capital, and TOBINQ is Tobins q, measured as market value of assets over book value of assets. InthismodelsalestocapitalratioandTobinsqrepresentfundamentalfactors,i.e.factorsthat capture the marginal productivity of capital. In the absence of market frictions, positive shocks to 3 See Gilchrist and Himmelberg (1998) for a derivation of the ratio of sales to capital as a measure of marginal productivity of capital. 194I. Love, L. Zicchino / The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance 46 (2006) 190210 these fundamental factors should lead to an increase in investment as fi rms will take advantage of better investment opportunities. Cash fl ow is commonly used in investment models as an indicator for internally available funds (see Hubbard, 1998, for a review). In our model, we consider cash fl ow also as a proxy for fi nancial factors.4Our analysis is implicitly based on an investment model in which, after controlling for the marginal profi tability, the effect of the fi nancial variables on investment is interpreted as evidence of fi nancing constraints.5We do this by relying on the orthogonalization ofimpulseresponses.Becausetheshocksareorthogonalized,i.e.fundamentalsarekeptconstant, theimpulseresponseofinvestmenttocashfl owisolatestheeffectofthefi nancialfactors.Weuse this orthogonalized response of investment to fi nancial factors as a measure of market frictions and fi nancing constraints. The impulse-response functions describe the reaction of one variable to the innovations in another variable in the system, while holding all other shocks equal to zero. However, since the actual variancecovariance matrix of the errors is unlikely to be diagonal, to isolate shocks to one of the variables in the system it is necessary to decompose the residuals in a such a way that they become orthogonal. The usual convention is to adopt a particular ordering and allocate any correlation between the residuals of any two elements to the variable that comes fi rst in the ordering.6The identifying assumption is that the variables that come earlier in the ordering affect the following variables contemporaneously, as well as with a lag, while the vari- ables that come later affect the previous variables only with a lag. In other words, the variables that appear earlier in the systems are more exogenous and the ones that appear later are more endogenous.7 In our specifi cation we assume that current shocks to the marginal productivity of capital (proxied by sales to capital) have an effect on the contemporaneous value of investment, while investment has an effect on the marginal productivity of capital only with a lag. We believe this assumption is plausible for two reasons. First, the sales to capital ratio is likely to be the most exogenous fi rm-level variable since it depends on the demand for fi rms output, which often is outsideofthefi rmscontrol(ofcourse,salesdependonfi rmsactionsaswell,butmostlikelywith a lag). Second, investment is likely to become effective with some delay since it requires time to become fully operational (the so-called “time-to-build” effect). We also argue that the effect of sales on cash fl ow is likely to be contemporaneous and if there is any feedback effect it is likely to happen with a lag. Finally, we assume that investment responds to cash fl ow contemporaneously, while cash fl ow responds to investment only with a lag.8In the model with four variables, we 4 Although cash fl ow is the most commonly used proxy for net worth, it is closely related to operating profi ts, and therefore to the marginal productivity of capital. If the investment expenditure does not result in higher sales but in lower costs (i.e. more effi ciency), the sales to capital ratio (our main measure of marginal productivity of capital) would not pick up this effect, while the cash fl ow would. Thus, cash fl ow may partly capture fundamental factors rather than the fi nancialfactorsaffectinginvestment.Toreducethise
温馨提示
- 1. 本站所有资源如无特殊说明,都需要本地电脑安装OFFICE2007和PDF阅读器。图纸软件为CAD,CAXA,PROE,UG,SolidWorks等.压缩文件请下载最新的WinRAR软件解压。
- 2. 本站的文档不包含任何第三方提供的附件图纸等,如果需要附件,请联系上传者。文件的所有权益归上传用户所有。
- 3. 本站RAR压缩包中若带图纸,网页内容里面会有图纸预览,若没有图纸预览就没有图纸。
- 4. 未经权益所有人同意不得将文件中的内容挪作商业或盈利用途。
- 5. 人人文库网仅提供信息存储空间,仅对用户上传内容的表现方式做保护处理,对用户上传分享的文档内容本身不做任何修改或编辑,并不能对任何下载内容负责。
- 6. 下载文件中如有侵权或不适当内容,请与我们联系,我们立即纠正。
- 7. 本站不保证下载资源的准确性、安全性和完整性, 同时也不承担用户因使用这些下载资源对自己和他人造成任何形式的伤害或损失。
最新文档
- 2025-2030中国金属包装容器制造行业现状调研及未来建设发展趋势预判研究报告
- 2025-2030中国速溶豆奶粉行业发展分析及发展前景与投资研究报告
- 2025-2030中国运动鞋行业市场深度调研及发展策略研究报告
- 2025-2030中国软胶囊包装机行业市场发展趋势与前景展望战略研究报告
- 2025-2030中国车辆子午线轮胎行业市场发展趋势与前景展望战略研究报告
- 2025-2030中国西餐行业市场发展前瞻及投资战略研究报告
- 2025-2030中国被褥行业市场发展趋势与前景展望战略分析研究报告
- 2025-2030中国蒸汽灭菌指示带行业市场发展趋势与前景展望战略研究报告
- 2025-2030中国营养品行业市场现状供需分析及重点企业投资评估规划分析研究报告
- 2025-2030中国节拍器行业市场发展趋势与前景展望战略研究报告
- 《道德与法治》六年级下《我们爱和平》课件
- 卫生法(教学讲解课件)
- 高三冲刺100天励志主题班会课件
- 全国工业产品生产许可证申请书
- 德能勤绩廉个人总结的
- 中层干部岗位竞聘报名表格评分表格评分标准
- 思想道德与法治课件:第六章 第一节 社会主义法律的特征和运行
- 有限空间作业及应急物资清单
- 《个人信息保护法》解读
- 新疆高速公路建设工程季节性施工方案
- 新版(七步法案例)PFMEA
评论
0/150
提交评论