版权说明:本文档由用户提供并上传,收益归属内容提供方,若内容存在侵权,请进行举报或认领
文档简介
FinanceandEconomicsDiscussionSeries
FederalReserveBoard,Washington,D.C.
ISSN1936-2854(Print)
ISSN2767-3898(Online)
NonlinearDynamicsinMenuCostEconomies?Evidencefrom
U.S.Data
AndresBlanco,CorinaBoar,CallumJones,VirgiliuMidrigan
2024-076
Pleasecitethispaperas:
Blanco,Andres,CorinaBoar,CallumJones,andVirgiliuMidrigan(2024).“NonlinearDynamicsinMenuCostEconomies?EvidencefromU.S.Data,”FinanceandEconomicsDiscussionSeries2024-076.Washington:BoardofGovernorsoftheFederalReserveSystem,
/10.17016/FEDS.2024.076
.
NOTE:StafworkingpapersintheFinanceandEconomicsDiscussionSeries(FEDS)arepreliminarymaterialscirculatedtostimulatediscussionandcriticalcomment.TheanalysisandconclusionssetfortharethoseoftheauthorsanddonotindicateconcurrencebyothermembersoftheresearchstafortheBoardofGovernors.ReferencesinpublicationstotheFinanceandEconomicsDiscussionSeries(otherthanacknowledgement)shouldbeclearedwiththeauthor(s)toprotectthetentativecharacterofthesepapers.
NonlinearDynamicsinMenuCostEconomies?
EvidencefromU.S.Data*
AndresBlancotCorinaBoar‡CallumJones§VirgiliuMidrigan¶
July2024
Abstract
Weshowthatstandardmenucostmodelscannotsimultaneouslyreproducethedispersioninthesizeofmicro-pricechangesandtheextenttowhichthefractionofpricechangesincreaseswithinflationintheU.S.time-series.Thoughthe
Golosovand
Lucas
(2007)modelgeneratesfluctuationsinthefractionofpricechanges,itpredicts
toolittledispersioninthesizeofpricechangesandthereforelittlemonetarynon-neutrality.Incontrast,versionsofthemodelthatreproducethedispersioninthesizeofpricechangesandgeneratestrongermonetarynon-neutralitypredictanearlyconstantfractionofpricechanges.
Keywords:menucosts,inflation,fractionofpricechanges.
*WethankHughMontagandDanielVillarforsharingthedataonthefractionofpricechanges.TheviewsexpressedherearethoseoftheauthorsandnotnecessarilythoseoftheFederalReserveBankofAtlantaortheFederalReserveBoard.
FederalReserveBankofAtlanta,
julioablanco84@.
NewYorkUniversityandNBER,
corina.boar@.
§FederalReserveBoard,
callum.j.jones@.
¶NewYorkUniversityandNBER,
virgiliu.midrigan@.
1
1Introduction
Arobustfeatureofthedataisthatthefractionofpricechangesincreasesinperiodsofhighinflation
.1
Itiswidelybelievedthatmenucostmodelscanreproducethispatternbecausefirmschooseendogenouslythetimingofpricechangesandaremorelikelytorespondtolargershocks.WhetherthisisindeedthecaseornothasimportantimplicationsfortheextenttowhichtheslopeofthePhillipscurvevariesinthetime-seriesandthereforethetradeoffbetweeninflationandoutputstabilizationfacedbymonetarypolicy.
2
BecauseinmenucostmodelsthedistributionofpricechangesalsocriticallyshapestheslopeofthePhillipscurveandthedegreeofmonetarynon-neutrality,
3
weevaluatetheabilityofstandardmenucostmodelstoreproducethecomovementbetweeninflationandthefractionofpricechangesintheU.S.data,whilesimultaneouslyaccountingforthelargedispersioninthesizeofpricechanges.Weconsiderthreecommonly-usedspecificationsforthetechnologyofchangingprices:(i)afixedmenucost,asin
GolosovandLucas
(
2007
),(ii)aCalvo-plusspecificationinwhichwithsomeprobabilityfirmscanchangepricesforfree,andotherwiseneedtopayafixedcost,asin
NakamuraandSteinsson
(
2010
)and(iii)aCalvo-plusspecificationaugmentedwithauniformdistributionofmenucosts,asin
Blanco
etal.
(2024a)
.
Weusethe
KrusellandSmith
(1998)approachtocharacterizethenon-linearsolutionof
eachmenucosteconomyinthepresenceofaggregatemonetarypolicyshocksandthenbackoutthesequenceofshocksthatexactlyreproducesthetimepathofinflationintheU.S.timeseries.Wefindthatthe
GolosovandLucas
(
2007
)modelpredictsthatthefractionofpricechangesincreasesconsiderablyinperiodsofhighinflation,asfirstpointedoutby
Nakamuraetal.
(2018),thoughlessthaninthedata
.4
Asiswellunderstood,however,thismodelpredictstoolittledispersioninthesizeofpricechanges.Incontrast,theothertwovariantsofthemodelthatbetterreproducethedispersioninthesizeofpricechangesimplyanearlyconstantfractionofpricechanges.
Weillustratetheimplicationsofthesepredictionsbystudyinghoweachoftheseeconomies
1See,forexample,
Gagnon
(2009),
Alvarezetal.
(2018),
KaradiandReiff
(2019),
Blancoetal.
(2024a)
and
Cavalloetal.
(2024)
.
2See
Blancoetal.
(2024b)whoshowthatamodelthatreproducestheincreaseinthefractionofprice
changesinperiodsofhighinflationimpliesasharpincreaseintheslopeofthePhillipscurveinthoseperiods,considerablyreducingtheoutputcostsofreducinginflation.
3See
CaballeroandEngel
(2007),
Midrigan
(2011)and
Alvarezetal.
(2016)
.
4
GolosovandLucas
(2007)and
Alvarezetal.
(2018)showthatthe
GolosovandLucas
(2007)model
reproducestherelationshipbetweeninflationandthefractionofpricechangesinacross-sectionofcountries.
2
respondstomonetarypolicyshocksofdifferentsizes.Becausethefractionofpricechanges
increasesconsiderablyinthe
GolosovandLucas
(
2007
)modelinresponsetolargemonetaryshocks,themodelpredictsimportantnon-linearities:therealeffectsfromlargershocksareproportionallysmallerthanthosefromsmallershocks.However,becausethemodelpredictslittledispersioninthesizeofpricechanges,therealeffectsofmonetarypolicyshocksaresmalleveninresponsetosmallshocks.Forexample,thecumulativeimpulseresponsetoa1%monetaryshockis0.14ofthatpredictedbytheCalvomodelwiththesameaveragefractionofpricechanges,andthattoa5%monetaryshockis0.08ofthatintheCalvomodel.Thus,inthe
GolosovandLucas
(2007)moneyisapproximatelyneutralregardlessofthesize
oftheshock.
Incontrast,theothertwovariantsofthemodelthatbetterreproducethedispersioninthesizeofpricechangespredictlargerrealeffects.However,becauseintheseeconomiesthefractionofpricechangesbarelyresponds,eventolargeshocks,theoutputeffectsarenearlylinearinthesizeoftheshock.Specifically,the
NakamuraandSteinsson
(
2010
)economypredictsacumulativeimpulseresponseofoutputtoa1%monetaryshockequalto0.36ofthatintheCalvomodelandtoa5%shockequalto0.30ofthatintheCalvomodel
.5
Similarly,theCalvo-pluseconomyaugmentedwithuniformmenucostspredictsacumulativeimpulseresponseofoutputtoa1%monetaryshockequalto0.58ofthatintheCalvomodelandtoa5%shockequalto0.56ofthatintheCalvomodel.
Ourpaperthereforecorroboratesthefindingsof
Blancoetal.
(
2024a
),wherewemadeasimilarpointusingU.K.micro-pricedata.Relativetothatpaper,herewefocusonasimplermenucosteconomywithoutstrategiccomplementaritiesinprice-settingandcalibratethemodeltomatchU.S.micro-pricestatistics.Inaddition,herewestudythecomovementbetweenaggregateinflationandthefractionofpricechanges,whereasin
Blancoetal.
(
2024a
)westudiedthecomovementbetweensectoralinflationandthefractionofpricechanges.
Weconcludethatanimportantchallengeforthemenucostliteratureistodevelopmodelsthatcansimultaneouslyreproducethemicro-pricedata,aswellastheextenttowhichthefractionofpricechangescomoveswithinflationinthetime-series.In
Blancoetal.
(
2024a
)weproposedonepotentialsolutiontothischallengeusingamenucosteconomyinwhichthelossesfrommisallocationfrompricedispersionwithinmulti-productfirmsarelow.Because
thatmodelreproducesthedispersioninthesizeofpricechangesinthedata,itpredicts
5
Auclertetal.
(2023)alsofindlittleevidenceofnon-linearityinthe
NakamuraandSteinsson
(2010)but,
unlikeus,theydonotconfrontthemodel’spredictionsonthecomovementbetweeninflationandthefractionofpricechangesinthetimeseries.
3
considerablerealeffectsfrommonetarypolicyshocks.Moreover,becauseitpredictsthat
thefractionofpricechangesincreasesconsiderablyintimesofhighinflation,italsopredictshighlynon-linearoutputresponsesandthereforeatime-varyingslopeofthePhillipscurve.
2MotivatingEvidence
Webrieflydescribetheevidencethatmotivatesourpaper.Figure
1
comparesthetimeseriesofU.S.inflationwiththatofthefractionofpricechanges.Wefollow
Nakamuraetal.
(
2018
)inmeasuringinflationusingthegrowthoftheConsumerPriceIndexexcludingshelter.Weusethedataonthefractionofpricechangescomputedby
Nakamuraetal.
(
2018
)usingpricequotescollectedbytheBureauofLaborStatistics.Thisserieswasrecentlyupdatedby
MontagandVillar
(2023)
.6
Wereporttheyear-on-yearchangeinthepriceindexand,forconsistency,theaveragemonthlyfractionofpricechangesintheprecedingyear.
Thefigureshowsthatthefractionofpricechangesincreasessystematicallywithinflation,aspointedoutby
Nakamuraetal.
(2018)and
MontagandVillar
(2023)
.7
Forexample,inthe1990s,wheninflationwaslow,approximately10%ofpriceschangedinagivenmonth.Incontrast,inthe1980s,wheninflationwashigh,approximately17%ofpriceschangedinagivenmonth.Morerecently,thepost-Covidincreaseininflationwasassociatedwithanevenhigherfractionofpricechanges,approximately23%permonth.
Figure1:InflationandtheFractionofPriceChanges
15
10
5
0
-5
0.25
0.15
0.05
inAation
1960198020002020
0.2
0.1
fractionofpricechanges
1960198020002020
Notes:TheshadedareasrepresentNBERrecessions.
6WethankHughMontagandDanielVillarforsharingthedatawithus.
7Thisisarobustfeatureofthedatathathasalsobeendocumentedforothercountries.See,forexample,
Gagnon
(2009),
Alvarezetal.
(2018),
KaradiandReiff
(2019),
Blancoetal.
(2024a)and
Cavalloetal.
(2024)
.
4
3Model
Weevaluatetheabilityofthemenucostmodeltoreproducethecomovementbetweenin-flationandthefractionofpricechangesinthedata.Weconsideraneconomyinwhichacontinuumofmonopolisticallycompetitivefirmsaresubjecttoidiosyncraticandaggregateshocksandfaceamenucostofchangingprices.Weconsiderthreespecificationsofthetech-nologyforchangingprices,allwidelyusedintheliterature:afixedmenucostasin
Golosov
andLucas
(2007),aCalvo-plusspecificationinwhichwithsomeprobabilityfirmscanchange
pricesforfreeasin
NakamuraandSteinsson
(
2010
),andauniformdistributionofmenucostsasin
Blancoetal.
(2024a)
.
3.1Consumers
Wefollow
GolosovandLucas
(2007)inassumingthatpreferencesarelogarithmicincon
-sumptionandlinearinhoursworked,soarepresentativeconsumermaximizes
subjectto
wherectisconsumption,htishoursworked,Ptistheaggregatenominalpriceindex,Btistheamountofgovernmentbondsthatpaythenominalinterestrateit,andDtdenotesprofits.Theoptimallaborsupplychoiceimpliesthatthenominalwageisequaltonominalspending,Wt=Ptct.
3.2MonetaryPolicy
WeassumethatmonetarypolicytargetsnominalspendingMt=Ptct,whichevolvesaccord-ingto
whereµt+1N(µ,σ).OurassumptionsonpreferencesimplythatWt=Mt.
3.3Technology
Thereisacontinuumofmonopolisticallycompetitiveintermediategoodsproducersi∈(0,1),eachproducingadifferentiatedvarietyusingalineartechnology
yit=zitlit,
5
wherezitisthequalityofthevarietyproducedbythefirmandlitistheamountoflabor
usedinproduction.
AperfectlycompetitivefinalgoodssectoraggregatesindividualvarietiesusingaCESaggregatorwithelasticityofsubstitutionσ
Thefinalgoodisusedforconsumptiononly,soyt=ct.Inadditiontoaffectingthefirm’sproductivity,thequalityzitalsoaffectsdemand.Ifpriceswereflexible,firmswouldrespondtoanincreaseinzitbyreducingpricesone-for-one,leavingquality-adjustedpricesandrevenuesunchanged.Theseshocksgenerateanidiosyncraticmotiveforfirmstochangetheirpricesandarewidelyusedinthemenucostliteratureduetotheirtractability.Weassumethatthezitevolvesaccordingto
logzit+1=logzit+εit+1,
whereεit+1~N(0,σ).
LettingPitdenoteanindividualfirm’sprice,thedemandfunctionforthefirm’soutputisgivenby
where
istheaggregatepriceindex.
3.4PriceAdjustmentTechnology
As
CaballeroandEngel
(2007),
Midrigan
(2011)and
Alvarezetal.
(2016)pointout,the
aggregateimplicationsofmenucostmodelsarecriticallyshapedbythedistributionofpricechanges.Wethereforeconsiderthreedifferentspecificationsforthepriceadjustmenttech-nologythatincreasinglyallowthemodeltoreproducethedistributionofpricechangesinthedata.First,wefollow
GolosovandLucas
(
2007
)andassumethatresettingpricesrequires
payingafixedmenucost.Second,wefollow
NakamuraandSteinsson
(2010)andassume
thatwithprobability1−λfirmscanchangepricesforfreeandwithprobabilityλtheyhave
topayafixedmenucost.Third,wefollow
Blancoetal.
(2024a)andassumethat,in
additiontothepossibilityoffreepricechanges,themenucostisidiosyncraticanddrawn
6
eachperiodforauniformdistributionU[0,].Inallthesecases,weassumethattheprice
adjustmentcostisdenominatedinunitsoflabor.Fromnowon,werefertotheseeconomiesasGL,NSandUniform,respectively.
3.5FirmObjective
Thefirmmaximizestheexpectedpresentvalueofprofits
whereτ=1/(σ−1)isasubsidythateliminatesthemarkupdistortionthatwouldariseevenwithflexibleprices,ξitisthepossiblyrandomcostofchangingpricesandIitisanindicatorequaltooneifthefirmadjustsitspriceandzerootherwise.
Tocharacterizethefirm’soptimalchoices,wefirstexpressitsobjectiveintermsofitspricegapwhichwedefineas
Similarly,wedefinetheaggregatepricegapastheCESweightedaverageoffirmpricegaps
Withthisnotationinplace,wecanwritethefirm’sobjectiveasafunctionofonlyitsownandaggregatepricegaps
Tocharacterizethepriceadjustmentdecision,let
denotethefirm’spricegapintheabsenceofapricechange,whichisalsothefirm’sidiosyn-craticstate.Eachperiodthefirmchooseswhethertoadjustitspriceornot.Ifthefirmdoesnotadjust,itspricegapisxit=sit.Ifthefirmadjustsitsprice,itresetsthepricegapto
xit=x,whichiscommontoallfirmsthatadjust.Thefirmrecognizesthatitsstateevolves
overtimeaccordingto
sit+1=xitexp(εit+1−µt+1).
Becausethisisamodelwithaggregateuncertaintyinwhichheterogeneousfirmsfollownon-lineardecisionrules,theentiredistributionofpricegaps,aninfinitedimensionalobject,
7
isnecessarytocharacterizetheequilibrium.Toseewhythisisthecase,letvdenotethe
valueofadjustingthepriceinperiodtandv(s)thevalueofnotadjustingthepricefora
firmwithidiosyncraticstates.Thefirmadjustsitspricewithprobability
inGLinNS
inUniform.
LettingFt(s)denotethedistributionoffirms,theequilibriumaggregatepricegapsatisfies
Thus,computingtheaggregatepricegapneededtosolvethefirm’sprobleminequation(
2
)requiresinformationabouttheentiredistributionoffirmpricegaps.
Wecircumventthecurseofdimensionalitybyusingthe
KrusellandSmith
(
1998
)approachtocharacterizehowXtevolvesovertimeasafunctionofasinglemomentofthedistributionofFt(s),namely
Specifically,wesimulatealonghistoryofmonetarypolicyshocks,calculatethetimeseriespathforStandXtimpliedbythemodelanduseprojectionmethodstoupdatetheperceivedaggregatepricegapfunction
Xt=X(St),
whereX(·)isalinearcombinationofChebyshevpolynomialsthatallowustocapturepo-tentialnon-linearities.
3.6Parameterization
Aperiodisamonthandwesetthediscountfactorβtoanannualizedvalueof0.96andtheelasticityofsubstitutionσequalto3.Following
NakamuraandSteinsson
(
2010
)and
Auclert
etal.
(2022),intheNSandUniformspecificationsoftheadjustmentcostweassumethat
thevalueofλissuchthat75%ofpricechangesarefree.
Table
1
reportstheresultoftheparameterization.Wecalibratethemeanandvolatilityofthemoneygrowthrateµandσm,thevolatilityofidiosyncraticqualityshocksσzandthe
menucostparametertotargettheaveragefractionofpricechanges,themediansizeofa
pricechange,andthemeanandstandarddeviationofinflation.Thesestatisticsarecomputed
8
fortheperiod1979-2014forwhich
Nakamuraetal.
(
2018
)reportamediansizeofregular
pricechangesof0.075.UsingthedatainFigure
1
,wecomputeanaveragefrequencyofpricechangesof0.105,anaverageannualizedinflationrateof3.4%andastandarddeviationofannualizedinflationof2.6%.AsPanelAofthetableshows,alleconomiesmatchthesetargetsperfectly.
PanelBofthetablereportstheparametervaluesrequiredtomatchthemoments.Since,aspointedoutby
BilsandKlenow
(2004)and
GolosovandLucas
(
2007
),theaveragesizeofapricechangeislargerelativetoaggregateinflation,themodelimpliesthatidiosyncraticshocksareapproximately3–4timesmorevolatilethanaggregateshocks.ThemenucostparameterisrelativelysmallintheGLeconomyandincreasesasweintroducerandomnessinthepriceadjustmentcosts.
Table1:Parameterization
A.Moments
DataGLNSUniform
I.Targeted
fraction∆p
0.105
0.105
0.105
0.105
median|∆p|
0.075
0.075
0.075
0.075
meaninflation
0.034
0.034
0.034
0.034
stddev.inflation
0.026
0.026
0.026
0.026
II.Not
targeted
kurtosis∆p
1.466
2.402
3.346
10thpctile|∆p
0.065
0.012
0.013
25thpctile|∆p
0.068
0.032
0.034
75thpctile|∆p
0.084
0.174
0.136
90thpctile|∆p
0.095
0.196
0.202
B.CalibratedParameterValues
GLNSUniform
μ
meanmoneygrowthrate
0.034
0.034
0.034
σm
s.d.monetaryshocks
0.008
0.009
0.010
σz
s.d.idios.shocks
0.024
0.037
0.037
menucost
0.015
0.246
2.818
Note:Themoneygrowthrateisannualized.Themenucostparameterisexpressedrelativetototalrevenue
inagivenperiod.
9
3.7TheDistributionofPriceChanges
Wenextinvestigatethemodels’implicationsforbroadermomentsofthedistributionofpricechanges.Figure
2
plotsthedistributionofpricechangesimpliedbyeachofthethreeeconomies.Asiswellunderstood,theGLmodelproducesabi-modaldistributionofpricechangeswithneitherverysmallnorverylargepricechanges.ThisisalsoreflectedintheuntargetedstatisticsreportedinPanelAofTable
1
whichshowsthatinthiseconomythedistributionofthesize(absolutevalue)ofpricechangesisverycompressed,rangingfroma10thpercentileof6.5%toa90thpercentileof9.5%.Analternativewayofsummarizingthedispersioninthesizeofpricechangesisthekurtosisofpricechanges,whichisequalto1.5.
BoththeNSandtheUniformeconomiesgeneratemoredispersioninthesizeofpricechangesandahigherkurtosis,butthedistributionintheNSeconomyhasjumps,reflectingthattheadjustmenthazardisastepfunction,asintheGLeconomy.Incontrast,thesmootheradjustmenthazardinducedbytheuniformmenucostdistributionintheUniformeconomyproducesasmoothdistributionofpricechanges.ThoughwedonothavedirectaccesstotheBLSmicro-pricedata,theevidenceonthedistributionofpricechangesinexistingstudiesismostconsistentwiththepredictionsoftheUniformeconomy.Forexample,usingthesameBLSdata
KlenowandKryvtsov
(2008)reportaunimodaldistributionof
regularpricechanges,with25%ofpricechangesbelow2.5%.Thispatternhasalsobeendocumentedforothercountries(see
Alvarezetal.,
2016
forFrance,
Blancoetal.,
2024a
fortheUKand
Gautieretal.,
forthcoming
for11Europeancountries),andforspecificsectors(see
Midrigan,
2011)
.8
4NonlinearDynamics?
Becausethefractionofpricechangesvariesovertimeinmenucosteconomies,thesemodelspredictpotentiallynonlinearresponsestoaggregateshocks.Wenextinvestigatetheextentofthesenonlinearities.
8Arecentpaperby
Alvarezetal.
(2021)usesdatafromagrocerystoreanddocumentsthat,after
controllingformeasurementerror,thedistributionofpricechangesisbimodal,featuringaconsiderabledipnearzero.Thisistrueforallthecountriesintheirsample,exceptfortheU.S.,forwhichthedistributionisunimodal.Suchabimodaldistributioncanberationalizedwithamodelwithrandommenucostsbutnofreepricechanges.WestudythismodelintheAppendixandshowthatithassimilaraggregateimplicationsastheNSandUniformeconomies.
10
Figure2:DistributionofPriceChanges
GL
40
30
20
10
0
-0.4-0.200.20.4
"p
6
4
2
0
NS
8
6
4
2
0
-0.4-0.200.20.4
"p
Uniform
-0.4-0.200.20.4
"p
4.1TheFractionofPriceChanges
WestartbygaugingtheabilityofeachofthethreeeconomiesabovetoreproducethefluctuationsinthefractionofpricechangesobservedintheU.S.timeseries.Tothatend,weusethenonlinearsolutionofeachmodeltobackoutthehistoryofmonetaryshocksμtthatallowseachmodeltoexactlyreproducethetimeseriesofinflationinFigure
1
.9
Figure
3
contraststheseriesforthefractionofpricechangesinthemodelandinthedata.Astheleftpanelshows,theGLmodelpredictssignificantmovementinthefractionofpricechanges,butnotasmuchasinthedata.Forexample,in1980thefractionofpricechangesinthedataincreasedto0.17andinthemodelitincreasedto0.14
.10
Similarly,duringthepost-COVIDinflationepisode,thefractionofpricechangesincreasedto0.23inthedataandtoonly0.13inthemodel.Overall,aregressionofthefractionofpricechangesontheabsolutevalueofinflationforthe1979-2014sampleperiodin
Nakamuraetal.
(
2018
)impliesaslopecoefficientof0.63%inthedataand0.32%inthemodel,sotheGLmodelgenerateshalfofthecomovementbetweeninflationandthefractionofpricechangesinthedata.
ThemiddleandrightpanelsofFigure
3
showthattheNSandUniformeconomiesimplymuchsmallerfluctuationsinthefractionofpricechanges:thefractionofpricechangesneverexceeds12%ineithereconomy.Theslopecoefficientfromregressingthefractionofpricechangesontheabsolutevalueofinflationis0.1%intheNSeconomyand0.07%inthe
9Forsimplicity,weassumedthatthemonetarypolicyshocksaretheonlysourceofaggregateuncertainty.Ourresultswouldbeidenticalifwealsoallowedforaggregateproductivityshocks,providedthesealsofollowarandomwalk,sincewhatmattersistheprocessfornominalmarginalcosts.
10Thesenumbersaresimilartothoseobtainedby
Nakamuraetal.
(2018)
.
0.25
0.15
0.05
Figure3:FractionofPriceChanges
0.2
0.1
0.25
0.15
0.05
GL
data
mod
el
1960198020002020
0.2
0.1
0.25
0.15
0.05
NS
1960198020002020
0.2
0.1
Uniform
1960198020002020
Notes:TheshadedareasrepresentNBERrecessions.
Uniformeconomy,muchsmallerthanthe0.63%inthedata.
In
Blancoetal.
(2024a)weshowthattheresponseofthefractionofpricechangesto
aggregateshocksdependsonthesizeoftheshockrelativetothedispersioninpricechanges.Modelsthataccountforthedispersionofpricechangespredictthatidiosyncratic,ratherthanaggregateshocksdeterminemostoftheadjustmentdecisions,renderingthefractionofpricechangesnearlytime-invariantwhenweconfrontthemodelwithaggregateshocksofsimilarmagnitudetothoseneededtoaccountfortime-seriesfluctuationsintheU.S.inflationrate.Forlargershocks,eventheseversionsofthemenucostmodelgeneratefluctuationsinthefractionofpricechanges.However,suchlargeshockswouldgeneratealotmorevariationininflationthanobservedinthedata.
Thus,weconcludethatnoneofthemenucostmodelsstudiedinthispapercansimul-taneouslyreproducethemicro-pricedataandthecomovementbetweeninflationandthefractionofpricechanges.Ontheonehand,versionsofthemodelthatgeneratesubstantialfluctuationsinthefractionofpricechanges,suchasGL,predicttoolittledispersioninthesizeofpricechanges.Ontheotherhand,versionsofthemodelthatreproducethelargedispersioninthesizeofpricechanges,suchasNSandUniform,predictanearlyconstantfractionofpricechanges.
Asweillustratebelow,thedispersioninthesizeofpricechangescriticallydeterminestherealeffectsofmonetaryshocks,andfluctuationsinthefractionofpricechangesarecrucialindetermininghownonlineartheserealeffectsare.Therefore,animportantchallengeformenucostmodelsistosimultaneouslyaccountforbothofthesefeaturesofthedata.In
Blancoet
11
12
al.
(2024a)weprovideonepotentialsolutiontothischallengeusingamulti-productmenu
costmodelwithalowdegreeofmisallocationinsidethefirm.
4.2RealEffectsofMonetaryShocks
Wenextinvestigatetheextentofnonlinearitiesthatthethreemodelsimplybystudyinghoweachoftheseeconomiesrespondst
温馨提示
- 1. 本站所有资源如无特殊说明,都需要本地电脑安装OFFICE2007和PDF阅读器。图纸软件为CAD,CAXA,PROE,UG,SolidWorks等.压缩文件请下载最新的WinRAR软件解压。
- 2. 本站的文档不包含任何第三方提供的附件图纸等,如果需要附件,请联系上传者。文件的所有权益归上传用户所有。
- 3. 本站RAR压缩包中若带图纸,网页内容里面会有图纸预览,若没有图纸预览就没有图纸。
- 4. 未经权益所有人同意不得将文件中的内容挪作商业或盈利用途。
- 5. 人人文库网仅提供信息存储空间,仅对用户上传内容的表现方式做保护处理,对用户上传分享的文档内容本身不做任何修改或编辑,并不能对任何下载内容负责。
- 6. 下载文件中如有侵权或不适当内容,请与我们联系,我们立即纠正。
- 7. 本站不保证下载资源的准确性、安全性和完整性, 同时也不承担用户因使用这些下载资源对自己和他人造成任何形式的伤害或损失。
最新文档
- 2025服装连锁加盟合同样本
- 2025海上运输合同模板书
- 二零二五年度车辆转让与道路救援服务合同3篇
- 二零二五年度股权投资公司股东合作协议3篇
- 二零二五年度文化产业发展全新期权合同3篇
- 2025年度养羊产业人才培养与交流合作协议3篇
- 二零二五年度生态保护公益合作合同3篇
- 2025年度虚拟现实合伙人股权分配与内容开发合同3篇
- 二零二五年度生态农业用地农村房屋买卖合同协议书
- 2025年度农村自建房包工与智能安防系统安装合同
- 3、心电图检查质量控制(操作标准化)要求
- 肾病科肾病综合征诊疗规范2023版
- 高考作文模拟写作训练:一个熟悉的劳动者
- 电商税收合规问题
- 铁路行车规章
- 污水处理厂有毒有害气体检测记录表
- 马克思主义与社会科学方法论课后思考题答案全
- 针灸推拿习题库+参考答案
- 浅析岩溶地区工程地质勘察手段及应用
- 2023-2024学年六年级上期末数学考试试卷附答案解析
- 罗伊模式个案护理
评论
0/150
提交评论