版权说明:本文档由用户提供并上传,收益归属内容提供方,若内容存在侵权,请进行举报或认领
文档简介
Automation
and
Welfare:The
Role
of
Bequests
andEducationPreparedby
ManukGhazanchyan,AlexeiGoumilevski,andAlexMourmourasWP/24/11IMFWorkingPapersdescriberesearchinprogressbytheauthor(s)andarepublishedtoelicitcommentsandtoencouragedebate.TheviewsexpressedinIMFWorkingPapersarethoseoftheauthor(s)anddonotnecessarilyrepresenttheviewsoftheIMF,itsExecutiveBoard,orIMFmanagement.2024JANWP/24/11©2023InternationalMonetaryFundAutomation
and
Welfare:
The
Role
of
BequestsandEducation*PreparedbyManukGhazanchyan,AlexeiGoumilevski,andAlexMourmourasAuthorizedfordistributionby
AlexMourmourasJanuary2024IMF
Working
Papers
describe
research
in
progress
by
the
author(s)
and
are
published
to
elicitcomments
and
to
encourage
debate.
The
views
expressed
in
IMF
Working
Papers
are
those
of
theauthor(s)anddonotnecessarilyrepresenttheviewsoftheIMF,itsExecutiveBoard,or
IMFmanagement.ABSTRACT:
This
paper
examines
the
welfare
effects
of
automation
in
neoclassical
growth
modelswith
and
without
intergenerational
transfers.
In
a
standard
overlapping
generations
model
without
suchtransfers,
improvements
in
automation
technologies
that
would
lower
welfare
can
be
mitigated
by
shiftsin
labor
supply
related
to
demographics
or
pandemics.
With
perfect
intergenerational
transfers
basedon
altruism,
automation
could
raise
the
well-being
of
all
generations.
With
imperfect
altruism,
fiscaltransfers(universalbasicincome)andpublicpolicies
toexpandaccesstoeducationopportunitiescanalleviatemuchofthenegativeeffectofautomation.JELClassificationNumbers:Keywords:E13,E62,D64Automation;
Aging;
Altruism;
Fiscal
Policy;
Education;OverlappingGenerationsmghazanchyan@;
agoumilevski@;amourmouras@Authors’E-MailAddresses:_________________________________________________________________________________________________⸸Manuk
Ghazanchyan
is
an
Economist
in
the
Western
Hemisphere
Department,
Alexei
GoumilevskiisaSeniorScientificComputingEngineerintheInformationandTechnology
Department,
andAlexMourmourasisDivisionChiefintheAsiaPacificDepartment.*Presented
at
the
28th
International
Conference
on
Computing
in
Economics
and
Finance
in
Dallas,Texas,
June
17-19th,
2022.
We
thank
conference
participants
for
their
useful
comments.
We
arealso
grateful
to
Peter
Rangazas,
Marina
Mendes
Tavares,
and
Jeremy
Clift
for
the
insightfulcommentsthatshapedourpaper.-2-ContentsI.Introduction
...............................................................................................................................................1II.RelevantLiterature...................................................................................................................................3III.AutomationandWelfareinOverlappingGenerationModels
.............................................................5B.IntroducingaOne-Timetax.................................................................................................................9C.K&SModelwithaBequest
...............................................................................................................11D.K&SModelwithBequestandEducation..........................................................................................141.2.PrivateEducation.......................................................................................................................15PublicEducation
........................................................................................................................17IV.ArtificialIntelligence.............................................................................................................................22A.K&SModel
........................................................................................................................................22IV.Conclusions
..........................................................................................................................................26Appendices.................................................................................................................................................27AppendixA.
K&SModelwithBequest.................................................................................................27AppendixB.
ReplicatingKotlikoffandSachs(2012)
...........................................................................31AppendixC.
RobustnessChecks........................................................................................................31A.References
....................................................................................................................................34-3-I.
IntroductionAutomation
has
accelerated
in
recent
decades,
driven
by
ongoing
improvements
in
computing
andinformation
technologies
and
associated
cost
reductions.
Machines
in
a
widening
range
of
industriesperform
increasingly
complex
tasks,
powered
by
sophisticated,
networked
software.
The
accelerationin
automation
and
its
economy-wide
diffusion
in
blue-
and
white-collar
occupations
alike
is
creating
newemployment
categories
but
is
also
contributing
to
widening
inequality
and
fueling
demand
forgovernment
policies
to
reverse
long-term
income
losses
of
labor.
This
long-standing
promise
andconcerns
are
vividly
illustrated
by
the
latest
breakthrough
in
Artificial
Intelligence
involving
generative,pretrainedtransformers.Looking
ahead,
while
the
pace
of
automation
is
likely
to
continue,
its
effects
may
be
mitigated
byoffsetting
forces.
Populations
are
aging
almost
everywhere.
In
the
advanced
economies,
the
working-agepopulationhasstartedshrinkingfor
thefirsttimesinceWorldWar
II(Spence,
2022).
Globally,thepopulation
ofworking
age
is
expected
tocontinue
togrow
until
about2040,butthe
ratio
ofthe
workingage
population
to
the
total
is
already
declining
globally
(Chart).
In
the
case
of
China,
for
example,
theworking-age
population
is
expected
to
shrink
by
a
fifth
over
the
next
30
years.
As
Goodhart
and
Pradhanstress,
our
age
is
one
of
demographic
reversal
in
which
the
“long
glut
of
inexpensive
labor
that
had
keptprices
and
wages
down
for
decades,
is
giving
way
to
an
era
of
worker
shortages,
and
hence
higherprices”.Recurring
global
pandemics
also
adversely
affect
labor
supply,
either
by
depressing
growth
in
the
laborforce
directly
(AIDS
pandemic),
or
indirectly
by
reducing
the
participation
of
older
workers
and
othersin
contact-intensive
occupations
(pandemic
related
to
Covid-19).
In
the
absence
of
mass
south-northmigration,
robots
may
turn
out
to
be
essential
in
meeting
more
of
the
needs
of
the
elderly
and
reversedeclinesinaggregateoutput
andwelfare1.This
paper
examines
the
combined
welfare
effects
of
automation
and
lower
labor
supply
usingneoclassical
growth
models
with
and
without
intergenerational
transfers.
It
begins
by
replicating
aversion
of
the
well-known
result
of
Kotlikoff
and
Sachs
(K&S,
2012)
that
a
one-time
improvement
in
thetechnical
efficiency
of
machines
ends
up
immiserating
all
future
generations.
This
striking
result
relieson
two
crucial
assumptions.
First,
machines
are
very
good
substitutes
for
unskilled
labor
throughoutthe
economy,
so
that
improved
automation
ends
up
displacing
workers
and
lowering
wages
across
theboard.
Second,
there
are
no
operative
intergenerational
transfers
of
any
kind,
so
that
the
owners
ofcapitalend
upconsumingthe
entirewindfallfrom
theimprovementsinautomationduringtheirlifetime(a
generation,
roughly
thirty
years).
The
positive
shock
to
the
efficiency
of
machines
does
not
raisesaving,
depresses
investment
in
physical
and
human
capital,
and
sets
in
motion
a
never-ending
cycleof
declining
welfare.
Government
policy
is
therefore
needed
to
spread
this
windfall
more
equitablyacross
future
generations.
K&S
consider
wealth
taxes,
in
particular
socializing
a
portion
oftheeconomy’scapitalstockthatallowsthegovernmenttofinanceasustainableincomestream(universalbasic
income)
for
all
future
generations.
Resorting
to
compulsion
is
essential
when
generations
areselfish,precludinganysortof
voluntaryintergenerationaltransfers.Infact,
privateintergenerationaltransfers
aresubstantial,
with
about
half
ofallhouseholdsplanning
toleave
estates
(Laitner
and
Juster,
2017).
The
first
objective
of
the
paper
is
to
reassess
the
welfareeffects
of
automation
in
the
presence
of
intergenerational
transfers,
both
bequests
and
privately
andpublicly
funded
schooling.
In
a
version
of
the
K&S
model
with
operative
bequests,
we
find
thatintergenerational
transfers
are
positive
in
equilibrium
if
the
strength
of
altruism
exceeds
a
certainthreshold,
mitigating
the
negative
effects
of
automation.
But
while
it
is
comfortable
to
know
that
thegains
from
automation
may
be
passed
to
future
generations
without
the
need
to
nationalize
capital,
thismodel
of
perfect
altruism
is
also
extreme:
many
families
in
each
generation
cannot
make
efficienttransferstotheirchildren.What
is
needed
is
a
more
balanced
model,
one
that
features
heterogeneity
both
within
and
acrossgenerations,
with
some
households
making
efficient
bequests
and
others
stuck
in
a
corner
solution.We
assess
whether
automation
is
immiserating
in
a
version
of
K@S
model
that
incorporates
purealtruism,
and
in
Glomm
and
Ravikumar’s
model
(G&R,
1992)
in
which
parents
make
investments
in
theschooling
of
their
children.
We
study
how
fiscal
and
educational
policies
can
best
raise
welfare,
byalleviatingfinancingconstraintsinthefinancingofhumancapitalinvestmentsandrestoringequalityofopportunity.Similar
results
obtain
in
a
version
of
the
model
used
by
Ivanyna,
Mourmouras
andRangazas
(2018)
in
with
two
types
of
households
(the
poor,
who
are
bequest-constrained)
and
the
rich(whoareunconstrained).The
paper
then
turns
to
an
analysis
of
a
combined
shock
involving
a
jump
in
automation
and
asimultaneous
reduction
in
labor
supply
driven
by
demographics.
As
expected,
strengthening
altruisticbondsraisebequestsandhumancapital
investmentsoftheyoung,providinganadditionalstimulustoeconomic
growth.
In
addition,
government
transfers
of
tax
revenue
levied
on
the
rich
can
improve
the1Businessleadershavealsomadeaconnectionbetweenautomationandagingrecently.
OneexamplewastherecentarticleinFortunebyIBMCEO,ArvindKrishnaherehepointstodecliningpopulationstocalmfearsaboutA.I.takingjobs.Hefurtheraddedthatultimately“thereisgoingtobejobcreation”withA.I.,asjobswillalsobeaddedinareaswithmorevaluecreation.-2-welfare
of
the
poor
and
reduce
inequality
within
and
across
generations
when
altruistic
links
betweengenerationsareweak.II.
RelevantLiteratureThe
literature
on
automation
and
its
economic
impact
is
evolving,
with
some
earlier
studies
from
Gordon(2012),
Cowen(2011),Acemoglu
andRestrepo(2017,2018),
SachsandKotlikoff
(2012,2015),
Ford,(2015);
Freeman,
(2015)
amongst
pessimists,
and
Brynjolfsson
and
McAfee
(2014),
Autor
(2014,
2015)among
the
optimists.
The
key
issue
is
whether
automation
replaces
labor
share
and
employmentthrough
replacement
of
routine
tasks
of
ever-increasing
scope
and
complexity
or
whether,
on
net,
itincreaseslaborparticipationbycreatinghigh-payingjobsinemergingnewoccupations.Somegloomyscenarios
for
labor
resulting
from
artificial
intelligence
and
simultaneous
automation
breakthroughs
aredescribed
in
Bostrom
(2014).
Graetz
et.
al.
(2018)
examined
the
economic
contribution
of
modernindustrialrobotsin17countriesfortheperiod1993-2007.Contrary
to
the
pessimistic
view,
these
authors
found
that
the
increasing
use
of
robots
raised
the
annualgrowth
of
GDP
and
labor
productivity
by
0.37
and
0.36
percentage
points,
respectively.
Authorsconclude
that
those
robots
did
not
significantly
reduce
total
employment,
although
they
did
reduce
low-skilled
workers’
employment
share.
Gaaitzen
et
al.
(2020)
studied
the
effects
of
adaptation
of
industrialrobots
and
occupational
shifts
by
task
content
in
the
thirty-sevencountries
for
the
period
from
2005
to2015.
The
authors
found
that
increased
use
of
robots
is
associated
with
positive
changes
in
theemployment
share
of
non-routine
analytic
jobs
and
negative
changes
in
the
share
of
routine
manualjobs.
Of
course,
enhancing
policy
including
R&D
and
the
regulatory
platforms
in
both
private
and
publicsectors
to
support
digital
technologies
is
key
to
improve
productivity.
While
the
2020-22
pandemichelped
to
accelerate
the
digital
transformation,
many
sectors
–
including
the
public
sector
–
are
lagging,andhenceconcernsabouttheeffectsofautomationonemploymentwillpersist(Spence,2022).Only
a
few
studies
examined
the
effect
of
automation
and
population
aging
on
the
labor
market
asidefrom
the
classical
work
by
Frey
and
Osborne
(2017)
focusing
on
the
probability
of
automation
affectingvarious
jobs
and
occupations.
One
of
the
earliest
studies
on
automation
and
population
aging
was
byAcemoglu
and
Restrepo
(2017),
where
the
authors
examined
the
relationship
between
economicgrowth,
population
aging,
and
automation
at
the
country
level.
Phiromswad
et
al
(2022)
is
amongst
themost
recent
studies
to
focus
on
those
effects
but
also
on
the
interaction
effects
of
automation
andpopulation
aging
on
the
labor
market.
Consistent
with
previous
literature
including
with
Graetz
andMichaels
(2018)
the
authors
found
strong
evidence
that
automation
negatively
affects
employmentgrowth
holding
other
factors
constant.
They
also
found
strong
evidence
that
the
disaggregatedmeasures
of
age-related
abilities
affect
employment
growth
but
not
the
aggregate
measure.
Asexpected
and
consistent
with
findings
that
automation
is
still
evolving
in
affecting
high
value
jobs,
theauthors
find
that
with
occupations
with
low
score
on
both
the
age-appreciated
cognitive
ability
as
wellage-depreciated
physical
ability
(such
as
production
occupations
and
food
preparation
and
servingrelated
occupations),
the
negative
effect
of
automation
on
employment
tends
to
be
strongest.
However,for
occupations
with
a
high
score
in
both
age-appreciated
cognitive
ability
as
well
as
age-depreciatedphysical
ability
(such
as
protective
service
occupations
and
healthcare
practitioners
and
technicaloccupations),thenegativeeffectofautomationonemploymenttendstobeweakest.Aghion-Jones-Jones
(2017)
study
the
implications
of
artificial
intelligence
for
economic
growth
in
lightof
reconciling
evolving
automation
with
the
observed
stability
in
the
capital
share
and
per
capita
GDPgrowth
over
the
past
century.
The
authors
create
sufficient
conditions
to
generate
overall
balanced-3-growth
with
a
constant
capital
share
that
stays
well
below
100
percent,
even
with
nearly
completeautomation.
In
other
words,
while
Baumol’s
cost
disease
leads
to
a
decline
in
the
share
of
GDPassociated
with
manufacturing
or
agriculture
(once
they
are
automated),
this
is
balanced
by
theincreasing
fraction
of
the
economy
that
is
automated
over
time.
The
authors
also
study
the
effects
ofintroducing
A.I.
in
the
production
technology
for
new
ideas
and
the
possibility
that
A.I.
could
generatesome
form
of
a
singularity,
where
the
authors
nevertheless
claim
that
the
Baumol
theme
here
alsoremains
relevant:
even
if
many
tasks
are
automated,
growth
may
remain
limited
due
to
areas
thatremainessentialyetarehardtoimprove.Pizzinelliandothers(forthcoming)examinetheimpactofArtificial
Intelligence
(AI)
onlabormarketsinboth
Advanced
Economies
(AEs)
and
Emerging
Markets
(EMs).
The
authors
propose
an
extension
toa
standard
measure
of
AI
exposure,
accounting
for
AI's
potential
as
either
a
complement
or
a
substitutefor
labor,
where
complementarity
reflects
lower
risks
of
job
displacement.
Then
they
analyze
worker-level
microdata
from
two
AEs
(US
and
UK)
and
four
EMs
(Brazil,
Colombia,
India,
and
South
Africa),revealing
substantial
variations
in
unadjusted
AI
exposure
across
countries.
The
authors
found
thatwhileAI
posesrisksoflabordisplacement
duetotaskautomation,
italsoholdspromiseinitscapacityto
enhance
productivity
and
complement
human
labor,
especially
in
occupations
that
require
a
highlevelofcognitiveengagementandadvancedskills.
TheauthorsalsofindthatAEsmayexpectamorepolarizedimpactofAIonthelabormarketandarethuspoisedtofacegreaterriskoflaborsubstitutionbutalsogreaterbenefitsforproductivity.The
extent
and
form
of
voluntary
intergenerational
transfers
is
dictated
by
the
strength
ofintergenerationalaltruismandisanimportantconsiderationinmacroeconomicsthatisrelevantforourpaper.
Kotlikoff
(2001)
provides
an
excellent
survey
of
key
works
on
the
role
of
intergenerationalaltruism,includingempiricalfindings—forexample,the
resultsofAltonjiandHayashi(1994)whichareconsistent
with
the
pure
altruism
theory.
A
closely
related
area
of
research
concerns
the
form
of
humancapital
investments,
specifically
the
rationale
behind
education
or
other
bequests
in
kind.
Razin
andRosenthal(1990)showthatfamilytaxationasaresponsetoinformationasymmetrybetweenaparentand
a
child
could
reduce
the
need
for
government
intervention
and
taxation.
Hood
and
Joyce
(2017)provideanexcellentupdatetotheempiricalrelevanceofaltruism.OurpaperismostcloselyrelatedtoMichel,Thibault,andVidal(2004),whostudytheeffectsofaltruismandfiscalpoliciesongrowthinanoverlapping
generations
model
in
the
tradition
of
Diamond,
and
to
Glomm
and
Ravikumar
(1992)
whostudy
bequests
in
the
form
of
human
capital
investments
in
children.
We
study
privately
fundedschoolingforfamilieswithoperativebequestsandpubliclyfundededucation.We
find
that
government
spending
on
education
promote
economic
growth.
These
conclusions
aresupported
by
a
vast
volume
of
research
that
link
individuals’
education
attainment
to
economy-wideprosperity.
Fabrizio
Carmignani
(2016)
studied
effects
of
government
expenditures
on
education
toeconomy.
Author
used
the
World
Bank's
World
Development
Indicator
database
data
on
151
countriesfor
2000
-
2010
years.
He
concluded
that
“increase
in
education
expenditure
by
1
point
of
GDPincreases
GDP
growth
by
0.9
percentage
points”.
Gheraia,
Zouheyr
et
al.
(2021)
investigatedrelationship
between
the
cost
of
education
and
economic
growth
in
the
Kingdom
of
Saudi
Arabia
forthe
period
1990-2017.
Authors
found
that
in
the
long
run
the
rise
in
educational
expenditure
by
1%would
lead
to
an
increase
in
economic
growth
by
0.89%.
Similar
results
were
obtained
by
Yahya,
Mohdet
al.
(2012).
Authors
analyzed
the
long-run
relationship
and
causality
between
the
governmentexpenditure
in
education
and
economic
growth
in
Malaysia
for
the
period
1970
to
2010.
Theyconcluded
that
economic
growth
is
positively
correlated
with
fixed
capital
formation,
labor
forceparticipation
and
expenditure
in
education.
Regarding
Granger
causality,
the
educational
expenditure-4-is
the
short-term
Granger
cause
of
economic
growth
and
vice
versa.
Mehmet
Mercana
et
al.
(2014)performed
cointegration
analysis
between
the
real
gross
domestic
product
and
total
expenses
to
theeducation
for
the
case
of
Turkey
for
the
period
1970-2012.
Authors
used
Autoregressive
DistributedLag
model
with
bounds
testing.
Authors
found
that
1%
increase
in
education
expenses
increaseseconomicgrowthby0.3%.III.
AutomationandWelfareinOverlappingGenerationModelsA.
AnAnalyticalTool:TheK&SModel(2012)We
begin
with
a
simple
model
featuring
two
period-lived
overlapping
generations
(OLG).
Each
period푡
=
1,2,
…
thepopulationconsistsofyoungandoldhouseholds.Theyoungareendowedwith
oneunitof
inelastically
supplied
unskilled
labor.
They
consume
part
of
this
income
and
invest
the
rest
in
physicalcapital
(machines,
푀)
and
in
their
own
human
capital
(skilled
labor,
푆).
Machines
and
human
capitalareperfect
substitutesin
savingportfolios.In
the
second
period
oflife,householdsrenttheirmachinesand
skills
in
perfectly
competitive
markets,
consuming
all
interest
and
principal.
Gross
output
푄
is
aconstant
elasticity
of
substitution
(CES)
production
function
of
the
economy-wide
stocks
of
푀,
퐿,
and푆:푄
=
푄(푁(푢푀,
퐿),
푆)(A.1)푀
and
퐿
combine
in
a
CES
production
function
with
elasticity
휀푀퐿
to
produce
an
intermediate
product푁,and푁
and푆
combineinaCESproductionfunctionwithelasticity휀푆푁
toproducethefinaloutput푄.The
parameter
푢
is
a
parameter
measuring
the
technical
efficiency
of
machinery.
A
rise
in
푢
is
a
puretechnical
advance.
Kotlikoff
and
Sachs
(KS,2012)
examine
whether
a
rise
in
푢
can
reduce
economicwellbeing,anoutcometheyrefertoas“im-mesmerizingproductivity.”Competitive
firms
hire
푀,
퐿,
and
푆
to
the
point
where
their
marginal
products
(denoted
as
푄
for
푖
=푖푀,
퐿,
and
푆)
equal
their
market
wages:
푄
=
푊
.
Following
K&S
the
partial
derivative
of
wage
with푖푖respecttoproductivityu
is,푑푙푛(푄
)퐿
⁄=
[휀푆푁
−휃휀푀퐿]⁄휀푀퐿(A.2)푑푙푛(푢)where
θ
is
the
share
of
skilled
labor
in
the
economy,
equal
to
(푄
∗푆)⁄푄.
We
see
that
a
rise
in푆machine’s
productivity
reduces
the
unskilled
wage
if
휀푀퐿
>
휀푆푁⁄휃.
Thus,
“im-mesmerizing”productivityismorelikelyif:◼
Substitutabilityofmachinesandunskilledlaborishigh(휀푀퐿
large)◼
Substitutabilityofintermediategoodsandskilledlaborislow(휀푆푁
small)◼
Theshareofskilledlaborinfinaloutputishigh(휃
high)Below
we
present
theoretical
underpinnings
for
the
K&S
conclusions.
Note
that
the
income
of
theyoung,퐼
,iscomprisedofwages푊
,partofwhichisinvestedinmachinesandhumancapital.Income푡푡-5-when
old,
퐼푡+1,
comes
from
the
ownership
of
machines
and
acquired
skills.
The
lifetime
budgetconstraintsofgenerationbornat푡,whoareyounginperiodtandoldat푡
+
1
are:퐼
=
퐿
푊
=
퐶
+
푆푣(A.3)(A.4)푡푡푡푡푡휕푄휕푄퐼푡+1
=
(
)
푀
+
(
)
푆=
퐷푡+1푡+1푡+1휕푀휕푆푡푡Here
퐶
is
the
consumption
when
young,
퐷is
consumption
when
old,
and
푆푣
is
saving,
which
is푡푡+1푡investedinmachinesandskills:푆푣
=
푀
+
푆푡+1(A.5)푡푡+1This
allocation
of
savings
is
made
under
perfect
foresight
to
maximize
utility,
so
that
investment
inmachines
and
skills
are
chosen
to
equalize
marginal
products
of
M
and
S
to
the
gross
interest
rate
intheeconomy:휕푄휕푄푅
=
(
)
=
(
)
=
1+
푟(A.6)푡푡휕푀휕푆푡푡
温馨提示
- 1. 本站所有资源如无特殊说明,都需要本地电脑安装OFFICE2007和PDF阅读器。图纸软件为CAD,CAXA,PROE,UG,SolidWorks等.压缩文件请下载最新的WinRAR软件解压。
- 2. 本站的文档不包含任何第三方提供的附件图纸等,如果需要附件,请联系上传者。文件的所有权益归上传用户所有。
- 3. 本站RAR压缩包中若带图纸,网页内容里面会有图纸预览,若没有图纸预览就没有图纸。
- 4. 未经权益所有人同意不得将文件中的内容挪作商业或盈利用途。
- 5. 人人文库网仅提供信息存储空间,仅对用户上传内容的表现方式做保护处理,对用户上传分享的文档内容本身不做任何修改或编辑,并不能对任何下载内容负责。
- 6. 下载文件中如有侵权或不适当内容,请与我们联系,我们立即纠正。
- 7. 本站不保证下载资源的准确性、安全性和完整性, 同时也不承担用户因使用这些下载资源对自己和他人造成任何形式的伤害或损失。
最新文档
- 春游出行活动策划书(3篇)
- 租赁合同附带担保抵押合同(3篇)
- 高中体育教学反思【15篇】
- 入职培训心得(12篇)
- 天津市2024-2025学年高一上学期11月期中考试 化学试题(无答案)
- 河南省通许县2024-2025学年八年级上学期期中考试道德与法治试卷
- 2024-2025学年浙江省金兰教育合作组织高一上学期期中考试数学试题(含答案)
- 绿色环保安全生产协议
- 调研报告:智障儿童家庭教育问题现状研究及建议
- 证券交易指定银行协议
- 边坡监测合同(与甲方)
- 《等边三角形》教学设计
- 血管外科试题合集
- 相贯线过渡线画法(课堂PPT)
- 医院传染病质控自查表
- 广告机质量检测报告(共6页)
- 中国 美国 日本水洗标志对比
- 通用横版企业报价单模板
- 潜油泵及潜油泵加油机讲义
- 物业服务公司各岗位规范用语
- 医患沟通内容要求记录模板(入院、入院三日、术前、术后、出院)
评论
0/150
提交评论