Comparing Bear and Tiger Democracy and Economic Reform in Russia and Korea_第1页
Comparing Bear and Tiger Democracy and Economic Reform in Russia and Korea_第2页
Comparing Bear and Tiger Democracy and Economic Reform in Russia and Korea_第3页
Comparing Bear and Tiger Democracy and Economic Reform in Russia and Korea_第4页
Comparing Bear and Tiger Democracy and Economic Reform in Russia and Korea_第5页
已阅读5页,还剩10页未读 继续免费阅读

下载本文档

版权说明:本文档由用户提供并上传,收益归属内容提供方,若内容存在侵权,请进行举报或认领

文档简介

1、comparing bear and tiger:democracy and economic reform in russia and koreakyung hoon leemseoul national universityi. relationship between democracy and economic reformcross-national research on the effects of democracy in developing countries reports mixed results. some studies find that democratic

2、regimes perform less well than authoritarian regimes, but some others argue the opposite. similarly, the effects of democratic transitions on economic performance show no clear-cut pattern (haggard and kaufman). nevertheless, conventional wisdom in the studies of transitions and reforms, mainly deri

3、ved from experiences in the south, was that there would be a trade-off between the radical neoliberal economic reform and the democratization or democratic consolidation (kaufman; stalings; przeworski; elster; armijo, beiersteker and lowenthal). that is, economic reform under new democracies is like

4、ly to be derailed as aggregate and distributive transitional costs of reform would erode peoples confidence in the reform or reform government. new democracies lack organizational and institutional infrastructures to resolve social conflicts in a more or less consensual and participatory way. so, th

5、e pessimism goes as far as to say, it might be unavoidable that strong executives should be brought back in after democratization to protect and insulate reform technocrats from diverse social pressure. then, the already weak democracies would be undermined further or stagnated (though not collapse)

6、 for the sake of economic reforms.experiences in post-communist seem to refute this conventional pessimism. according to some scholars, in the post-communist countries, consolidation of electoral democracy and improvement in political accountability tend to contribute to the success of economic refo

7、rm by reducing the governments arbitrary policy-making and well-positioned social actors rent-seeking. therefore, in this view, democratization/democratic consolidation and economic reform may be not only compatible but also even mutually reinforcing depending on the regional contexts. let me briefl

8、y mention only a few significant studies that show how it is so.political recommendations based on the conventional interpretations about the politics of economic reform have been put into question. the political dynamics of economic reform is usually based on an assumption about the distribution of

9、 the costs and benefits of reform, visualized as the j-curve. the j-curve depicts that losses from the economic reform are concentrated among specific groups while the benefits of reform are more widely dispersed. therefore, the losers should have greater selective incentives to engage in collective

10、 action than the winners. accordingly, in this view, for the success of economic reform, it becomes particularly important for the reformers to weaken or control the losers, while empowering the winners. hellman (1998) argues that the gains of reform are highly concentrated in particular groups of w

11、inners in the short term; by contrast, the costs of reform are dispersed throughout the economy. these transitional winners (such as enterprise directors, local administrations, and financial-industrial groups in russia) should have greater selective incentives to engage in collective action. they o

12、ften seek to stall the economy in a partial reform equilibrium that generates concentrated rents for themselves, while shifting unfair share of costs on the rest of society. if this is the case, the transitional winners, rather than losers, should be controlled or weakened for the success of economi

13、c reform. reducing chances for influential groups rent-seeking requires not insulation of executives but more transparency and wider participation in the decision-making process than the j-curve theorists usually assume. another popular belief that unconstrained executive authority is more likely to

14、 yield “coherent” reform programs seems to be groundless. by comparing privatization in hungary, germany, and the czech republic, star and bruszt (1998) show that state capacity to formulate and implement coherent reform packages can be enhanced by limitations on the unilateral prerogatives of execu

15、tive authority. deliberative institutions of horizontal accountability, through which executives are held accountable by other state institutions and held in check by organized societal actors, promotes pragmatism and reflexive learning, thereby reducing big policy mistakes or abrupt policy reversal

16、s. viewed in this way, the constrained executives ironically turn out to be more able to sustain peoples confidence and coherent reform packages. political reforms to promote democracy are even seen as prerequisite for economic reforms. referring to the problematic privatization in russia as well as

17、 latin america, linz and stephan (1996) warn against the danger of “inverting the legitimacy pyramid,” that is, privileging economic reforms first while neglecting political reforms, especially state reconstruction. the market reforms cannot be implemented effectively nor legitimized without strong

18、and democratic regulatory state power. in addition, political reforms have tactical virtue serving for reformers. on the short and medium range time horizon, voters can make independent and even disparate assessments about political and economic trends. therefore, given that the social and economic

19、situation deteriorates during reform, it is necessary to help voters separate their judgements about politics and economics, and thereby expand their time horizons. if the voters assessments about politics are positive, they can provide a valuable cushion against painful and unfair economic restruct

20、uring. in a nutshell, political reforms to promote democracy and economic reforms seem to be not only compatible but also mutually reinforcing at least in post-communist transitions in spite of significant strains between the two. in fact, statistically significant positive relationship exists betwe

21、en the two in post-communist contexts (fish). then, are democracy and economic reform still largely incompatible in the south whereas compatible in the east? bunces answer is firmly negative in the case of south. bunce (1998) sees the compatibility derived from distinctive feature of communist legac

22、ies; the neoliberal reforms is seen to promote liberal democracy as far as it purports to shatter the “fusion of politics and economics” under communist rule (also see greskovits). on the other hand, bunce simply accepts the conventional pessimism in the case of the south, so does not suggest any ne

23、w explanation regarding why virtuous cycle of political and economic reforms is necessarily impossible in the south. in this paper, by examining the case of korea, i would venture to argue that bunce exaggerates inter-regional differences at the expense of significant intra-regional heterogeneity. i

24、i. the case of korea: reforming the developmental state in korea, not only the crisis itself but also a dramatic change in the assessment of the korean developmental state, both domestically and abroad, has been propelling the present economic reform. the korean economic crisis itself began as a twi

25、n crisis, a currency crisis and a financial crisis. a wide range of factors responsible for the crisis such as the instability of the international financial system, weaknesses in domestic fundamentals and policy missteps have been identified. see, for example, imf (1997), radelet and sachs (1998),

26、krugman (1998), corsetti, pesenti and roubini (1998), shin and hahm (1998), balino and ubide (1999), and sonn (1998). while the relative strength of these diverse causes will be further debated, it is important to note that the reformers and the public perceived domestic causes as the most significa

27、nt. and, from the beginning, the crisis was not interpreted merely as an economic one; rather, it was diagnosed as a systemic failure of a developmental state that had been successful in the past (cho; im 1999; yun).the most salient feature of the developmental state was the state control of finance

28、 used to achieve industrial policy goals. as woo-cumings (pp. 19-20) points out, the developmental state as such can be good, bad, or ugly. it is good as far as it effectively promotes international competitiveness. it is bad because the state-business collusion generates corruption and moral hazard

29、; in korea, the states control of credit supply (so-called policy loans) and its intervention in the management of otherwise private financial institutions had encouraged chaebols over-expansion and moral hazard, and created inefficiencies and distortions in the financial system. it can also be ugly

30、 because it tends to be undemocratic and repressive. the korean developmental state, founded by park chung-hee more than three decades ago, had all three faces.however bad and ugly it really were, the korean developmental state successfully achieved goals of industrial policy because it had sufficie

31、nt autonomy vis-vis domestic social forces - including capital and labor. but, despite its control of the industrial sector, the states autonomy had been rapidly diminishing since the mid-1980s. the decline was due to the combined effects of two changes. one was the reversal in the state-business re

32、lationship itself. in fact, since 1970s the government-chaebol relationship had steadily moved from “dominance to symbiosis” (kim, eun mee) and then to “structural dependence” of the state on chaebols (im 1998). the state, which had been able to “discipline” the chaebols (amsden 1989) and “govern” t

33、he market (wade 1990), became extremely vulnerable to capital strikes by chaebols and the moral hazard of “too big to fail.” the other was the conservative nature of democratization since 1987. chaebols that had supported the military regime not only survived unpunished, but remarkably increased the

34、ir influence under the democratic rule by contributing astronomical sums of political monies needed for election campaigns. captured by the chaebols interests, the “democratized” state could not enforce economic restructuring even though the state anticipated economic deterioration. the latter obser

35、vation confirms one of the transitologists arguments that the modes of transitions do greatly matter. the mode of the transition in korea had facilitated the democratization but left lingering legacies partly responsible for the recent crisis. the authoritarian regimes economic success softened the

36、political transition by dampening the otherwise bitter distributional struggle between classes. more importantly, thanks to its economic success, the authoritarian regime, though weakened, still could influence the terms of transition. this influence reduced risks to conservatives from accepting ele

37、ctoral competition as the rule of game. the compromises between authoritarian and democratic elites resulted in weak break with the authoritarian past, which, in turn, constrained progress in reforms on the social, economic, and legal fronts. though the korean government and many academicians antici

38、pated the deterioration of economic performance in case of failure to find a new model of development, cohabitation of heterogeneous forces within the ruling coalition derailed the efforts to reform the economy. another major lingering authoritarian legacy was the continued privileges given to the m

39、ilitary. the special status given to the military was relatively swiftly abrogated when in the early stage of his presidency kim young-sam forcefully purged from the armed forces the hanahwoe, a core faction of politicized officers that had supported the authoritarian regime. in comparison, social a

40、nd economic reforms turned out to be much more difficult to implement. particularly, as mentioned above, chaebols successfully survived and prospered despite the governments repeated attempts to rein them. without comparable reforms in the chaebol sector, reforms in other sectors were also political

41、ly risky; an example can be seen in the episode of the aborted reform for labor flexibility at the end of 1996. in addition, the compromises with the authoritarian forces allowed the defects of “democratization backwards” to persist in the cases of “democratization backwards,” electoral democracy ha

42、s been introduced and almost consolidated before the basic institutions of a modern state such as the rule of law, institutions of civil society, and horizontal accountability of the governors are firmly established (rose and shin).; after the democratization, corrupt cronyism became even more rampa

43、nt because of the continued lack of transparency and accountability in both public and private sectors. in sum, the conservative nature of democratization was partly responsible for the outbreak of the crisis (song).the financial crisis itself did not occur in the absence of efforts to reform the de

44、velopmental state. on the contrary, it occurred in the midst of financial reforms begun in the early 1980s. the state had already broken away from a strategy of industrial development supported by directed lending and had been taking steps towards financial liberalization and deregulation. particula

45、rly, financial market liberalization accelerated under the kim young-sam presidency. in the absence of a concomitant strengthening of bank credit management skills and prudential supervision, the partial financial and capital account liberalization proceeded without appropriate mechanisms for the ev

46、aluation and the control of risk. lack of a unified system for supervision and regulation created the conditions for regulatory arbitrage and the development of risky practices, especially in commercial banks trust businesses and merchant banks operations. for details on the financial reform in kore

47、a since 1980s, see park and kim (1994), nam (1994), balino and ubide (1999), and borensztein and lee (1999). however, the government-led reforms were often faced with the chaebols strong lobby and related political barriers. further, the scope was too limited. despite the liberalization of capital m

48、arket, the structural problems of a developmental state - the governments arbitrary intervention, connected lending and lack of prudential regulation and supervision - remained substantial in korea. the result was the worst combination of “bad” face of the developmental state (state-business collusi

49、on) and partial/imprudent liberalization that disabled the “good” face of the developmental state (the capability of the government to effectively guide industrial development). it is well known that liberalization per se does not deliver public good. without well-run financial systems and high stan

50、dards of transparency and governance, the liberalization of markets and international capital flows provides another chance for rent-seeking, as best shown in russia. to a certain extent, this is also what happened in korea. in korea, the drive for globalization and liberalization did not reduce the

51、 rent-seeking on the part of chaebols. on the contrary, lobbying for and taking advantage of the liberalization unaccompanied by prudent regulatory supervision on foreign borrowing and investment enabled chaebols to increase their power, continue collusive practices and abuse their market power. the

52、 financial liberalization without adequate supervision led to the careless accumulation of debts in corporate and financial sectors. however, chaebols were only one of culprits in the nations financial meltdown. underlying the systemic failure, it was perceived, was crony capitalism, a vicious symbi

53、osis among politicians, state bureaucrats and chaebols. the intimate connection between the government, financial institutions, and the chaebols was once praised as so-called “embeddedness” of the successful developmental state (evans). however, the state-business collusion via the states control of

54、 finance, epitomized as gwanchi-geumyung (government-controlled financial system) and jeongkyong-yuchak (politics-business connection), had also long been criticized for moral hazard, corruption and illegitimacy. nevertheless, calls for dissolving the seemingly “successful” model were not current in

55、 mainstream society, and the government-led reforms could not but repeatedly fail as long as they did not attempt to overhaul the problematic “embeddedness” itself. the virtue of the crisis in 1997 was that it proved extreme fragility and instability inherent in the developmental state, and thereby

56、shattered from the bottom the lingering mirage of “illegitimate but probably effective” model of development. in this vein, though the outbreak of the crisis was deplorable and humiliating, it could be depicted and even welcomed as an opportunity for not simply restructuring the economy but fundamen

57、tally reforming the korean society as a whole. as a matter of fact, in korea, like elsewhere, neoliberal reform has exacerbated social and economic inequality and poverty, and thereby weakened so-called “substantive” democracy. but, if bunces logic is applied here, the present economic reform can co

58、ntribute to political and “procedural” democracy to the extent that it aims to eliminate the illegitimate “collusion of the state and business,” a major obstacle that has hindered the deepening of democracy in korea. on the other hand, the improvement in the democratic governance is required for the

59、 success of economic reforms given the fact that the absence of the rule of law and accountability in public as well as private sector eventually led to the crisis in 1997. to conclude, the economic reform and democratic deepening are perhaps no less compatible in the south than in the east. or, at least, russia and korea seem to share the same trouble; that is, deficit in democracy, not the excess, is the major obstacle for the consolidation of economic reforms. iii. politics of economic refor

温馨提示

  • 1. 本站所有资源如无特殊说明,都需要本地电脑安装OFFICE2007和PDF阅读器。图纸软件为CAD,CAXA,PROE,UG,SolidWorks等.压缩文件请下载最新的WinRAR软件解压。
  • 2. 本站的文档不包含任何第三方提供的附件图纸等,如果需要附件,请联系上传者。文件的所有权益归上传用户所有。
  • 3. 本站RAR压缩包中若带图纸,网页内容里面会有图纸预览,若没有图纸预览就没有图纸。
  • 4. 未经权益所有人同意不得将文件中的内容挪作商业或盈利用途。
  • 5. 人人文库网仅提供信息存储空间,仅对用户上传内容的表现方式做保护处理,对用户上传分享的文档内容本身不做任何修改或编辑,并不能对任何下载内容负责。
  • 6. 下载文件中如有侵权或不适当内容,请与我们联系,我们立即纠正。
  • 7. 本站不保证下载资源的准确性、安全性和完整性, 同时也不承担用户因使用这些下载资源对自己和他人造成任何形式的伤害或损失。

评论

0/150

提交评论