




版权说明:本文档由用户提供并上传,收益归属内容提供方,若内容存在侵权,请进行举报或认领
文档简介
CanEnergySubsidiesHelpSlayInflation?
ChristopherErceg,MarcinKolasa,JesperLinde,
andAndreaPescatori
WP/24/81
IMFWorkingPapersdescriberesearchin
progressbytheauthor(s)andarepublishedto
elicitcommentsandtoencouragedebate.
TheviewsexpressedinIMFWorkingPapersare
thoseoftheauthor(s)anddonotnecessarily
representtheviewsoftheIMF,itsExecutiveBoard,
orIMFmanagement.
2024
APR
N
Ann
R
INTERNATIONALMONETARYFUNDii
©2024InternationalMonetaryFund
WP/24/81
IMFWorkingPaper
MonetaryandCapitalMarketsDepartment
ResearchDepartment
CanEnergySubsidiesHelpSlayInflation?*
ChristopherErceg,MarcinKolasa,JesperLinde,AndreaPescatori
AuthorizedfordistributionbyChristopherErceg
April2024
IMFWorkingPapersdescriberesearchinprogressbytheauthor(s)andarepublishedtoelicit
commentsandtoencouragedebate.TheviewsexpressedinIMFWorkingPapersarethoseofthe
author(s)anddonotnecessarilyrepresenttheviewsoftheIMF,itsExecutiveBoard,orIMFmanagement.
ABSTRACT:Manycountrieshaveusedenergysubsidiestocushiontheeffectsofhighenergypricesonhouseholdsandfirms.AfterdocumentingthetransmissionofoilsupplyshocksempiricallyintheUnitedStatesandtheEuroArea,weuseaNewKeynesianmodelingframeworktostudytheconditionsunderwhichthesepoliciescancurbinflation.Wefirstconsideraclosedeconomymodeltoshowthataconsumersubsidymaybecounterproductive,especiallyasaninflation-fightingtool,whenappliedgloballyorinasegmentedmarket,atleastunderempiricallyplausibleconditionsaboutwage-setting.Wefindmorescopeforenergysubsidiestoreducecoreinflationandstimulatedemandifintroducedbyasmallgroupofcountrieswhichcollectivelydonothavemuchinfluenceonglobalenergyprices.However,theconditionsunderwhichconsumerenergysubsidiesreduceinflationarestillquiterestrictive,andthistypeofpolicymaywellbecounterproductiveiftheresultingincreaseinexternaldebtishighenoughtotriggersizeableexchangeratedepreciation.Sucheffectsaremorelikelyinemergingmarketswithshallowforeignexchangemarkets.Iftheprimarygoalofusingfiscalmeasuresinresponsetospikesinenergypricesistoshieldvulnerablehouseholds,thentargetedtransfersaremuchmoreefficientastheyachievetheirgoalsatlowerfiscalcostandtransmitlesstocoreinflation.
JELClassificationNumbers:E32,E52,E64,H23,Q43
Keywords:
EnergyPrices;EnergySubsidies;MonetaryPolicy;InternationalSpillovers
Author’sE-MailAddress:
CErceg@IMF.org,MKolasa@IMF.org,JLinde@IMF.org,andAPescatori@IMF.org
*WethankTianchuQiandKailiChenforexcellentresearchassistanceandTobiasAdrian,JaebinAhn,GiovanniDell'Ariccia,Pierre-OlivierGourinchas,ZoltanJakab,andMathiasTrabandtforusefulcommentsanddiscussions.ThepaperalsobenefitedfromcommentsfromtheparticipantstotheCEPRParisSymposium,ESSIMinTarragona,NBU-NBPARCinCracow,CEFinNice,SummerWorkshoponEconomicsandFinanceinWarsaw,andseminarsattheEuropeanCentralBank,Bancad'Italia,andUniversityofOttawa.TheviewsexpressedhereareoursanddonotnecessarilyrepresenttheviewsoftheIMF,itsExecutiveBoard,orIMFmanagement.
1
1Introduction
Centralbankshavetightenedmonetarypolicyaggressivelytocombathighinflation,whichsurgedtomulti-decadepeaksinmanyeconomies.Whiletheinflationrunuphasbeendrivenbyanumberoffactors,includingsupplydisruptionsandmassivefiscalandmonetarystimu-lus,sharpincreasesinenergypriceshavebeenamajorcatalyst.Manycountriesrespondedbyusingvariousformsofenergysubsidies,oftentargetedmainlytohouseholds,tohelpcurb
inflationaswellastocushiontheeffectsonhouseholdpurchasingpower(Arreguietal.
,
2022
;
Sgaravattietal.
,
2023).Energysubsidiesareviewedbymanypolicymakersashelpful
inthefightagainstinflationonthegroundsthattheyarelikelytolimitbothfirstandsecondroundeffects,includingbyreducingpassthroughtowages.
Buttherearemanyopenquestionsabouttheconditionsunderwhichenergysubsidiesareactuallylikelytobeeffectiveinloweringinflation,or,conversely,whentheymaybecoun-terproductive.Whilewagestickinesshaslongbeenrecognizedaspivotalinthetransmissionofenergyshockstooverallpriceinflation(e.g.,
BlanchardandGali
,
2007),therehasbeen
littleanalysisofhowtheeffectsofenergysubsidiesoninflationdependonthemodalitiesofwage-setting,includingthedegreeofindexation.Similarly,itisunclearhowtheeffectsofsubsidiesdependonthestructureoftheenergymarket:couldinsulatingconsumersfromtheeffectsofhigherpricesinahighlysegmentedmarket–suchastheonefornaturalgasinEurope–hurtfirmsenoughtocausecoreinflationtorise?Andhowdotheeffectsofsubsidiesdependonwhethertheyareusedbyasingle“smalleconomy”orabroadsetofcountries?
Inthispaper,weuseaNewKeynesianmodelingframeworktohelpanalyzetheseques-tions,butfirstseekempiricalgroundingbyestimatinghowoilshockstransmittotheeconomyintheUnitedStates(US)andeuroarea(EA).Specifically,weuseaproxySVARapproachwheretheinstrumentisgivenbysurprisechangesinoilpricesfollowingtheannouncementofOPECmeetingdecisions.Theseriesofsurprisesisadoptedfrom
Ka¨nzig
(2021)andaggre
-gatedtoquarterlyfrequencyoverthe1983to2019sampleperiod.Fortheseidentifiedshocks,wefindthatanegativeoilsupplyshockwhichdrivesupthepriceofoilleadstohighercoreandheadlineinflation,lowerGDP,andhigherpolicyratesinitiallyinboththeUSandtheeuroarea.Importantly,wefindsignificantdifferencesinthetransmissiontowagesbetweenthesetwoeconomies,withoilpricehikeshavingsmalleffectsonnominalwagesintheUS–sothatrealwagesfallnotably–whereastheytendtoboostnominalwagesenoughintheeuroareathatthereal(product)wageactuallyrises.Thesedifferencesinwagetransmissionturnouttohavecriticalbearingonhowenergysubsidiesaffectinflation.
Turningtoourtheoreticalframework,webeginbyconsideringasimpleworkhorseclosedeconomymodelwithnominalwageandpricestickinessthatbuildson
Bodensteinetal.
(2011)
.Asinthatmodel,weassumetheeconomyhasanendowmentofenergythatisutilizedbothinproductionandconsumption,butenrichthesupplyblockbyallowingfor
2
alternativeformsofdynamicwageindexationwherewagesmayadjusttoeithercoreorheadlineinflation.Wealsoincorporateenergysubsidiesthatareproportionaltoenergyuse,thusresemblingthedominanttypeofsubsidiesintroducedinmanycountries,includingtheUSandEurope.
Usingthismodel,wedemonstrateformallythatprovidingenergysubsidiestoconsumersisessentiallyequivalenttotaxingenergyusebyfirms:bothpoliciesdecreasetheeffectiveenergycosttohouseholdswhileincreasingthatfacedbyfirms,thusresultinginthesameallocations
.1
Theimplicationisthatwhileconsumerenergysubsidiescanbedesignedtoshieldhouseholdsfromariseintherelativepriceofenergy(sayduetoasupplyshock),suchapolicyisessentiallyataxonfirmsthatdrivesuptheirmarginalcostsofproduction.
Weshowhowalog-linearizedversionofthemodelwithenergycanbeexpressedinaformisomorphictothatof
Ercegetal.
(2000),andusethisformulationtoderiveastriking
analyticalresult.Inparticular,weshowthatenergysubsidiestoconsumersnecessarilyboostcorepriceinflationifmonetarypolicykeepsemploymentatpotentialandwagesareindexedtocoreinflation(eitherfullyorpartially,includingthespecialcaseofnoindexation).Thisresultholdsforanyconfigurationofparametersassumingthatveryweakconditionsaresat-isfied(i.e.,implyingthatadverseenergyshocksreducethepotentialrealwage).Intuitively,whileconsumersubsidiesdamptheinitialriseinheadlineinflation,thesubsidiesdriveuptheenergypricesfacedbyproducers,whichtheypassalonggraduallythroughraisingproductprices.Hence,thesesubsidiesmakeinflation–bothcoreandheadline–morepersistent.
Theclosedeconomymodelisrelevantforconsideringthelikelyeffectsofconsumerenergysubsidiesintheglobaleconomywhenallcountriespursuesimilarpolicies,orinahighlysegmentedenergymarket(suchasfornaturalgasinEurope).Inshort,wefindusingquantitativesimulationsofourmodelthatevenahighdegreeofindexationtoheadlineconsumerpriceinflation–wellabovewhatwefindempiricallyfortheUS,oreventheeuroarea–isnotenoughforconsumerenergysubsidiestoreducecoreinflation.Thesesubsidiesindeedreducefirst-roundeffectsonheadlineinflationinresponsetoanenergypricespikeandthisreducesupwardpressureonwages,buttheyalsocausethepre-subsidyenergypricefacedbyfirmstoriseenoughthatthe“all-in”effectisariseincoreinflation.Welfareanalysisusingtheusualutility-basedmetricconfirmsthatconsumerenergysubsidieslowerwelfare.
Whileourworkhorsemodelcastsstrongdoubtontheabilityofconsumersubsidiestolowerinflationwhenappliedglobally,itstillmightbeexpectedthatasmallopeneconomy–orgroupofcountriestoosmalltoaffectglobalenergyprices–mightbeabletousesubsidiestolowerinflation.Toexplorethis,weuseatwo-countryextensionwithincompleteassetmarkets.Thisvariantallowsforthetransmissionofenergysupplyshockstodiffersubstantiallyacrossenergy-importersandexporters,andalsodependonthedepthofthe
1Thesealternativeapproachesdohavedifferentimplicationsforthepre-subsidyenergyprice,withtheconsumersubsidydrivinguptheenergyprice,andthetaxonfirmsdrivingitdown(hence,allocationswouldbeaffectedinasettingwithendogenousoilproduction).
3
foreignexchangemarketwhichheavilyinfluencestheexchangerateresponse.
Focusingonthesmallopeneconomycase,wefindmorescopeforconsumerenergysubsidiestoreducecoreinflationthanintheclosedeconomymodel.Thisseemsintuitive:suchsubsidiesshould“chokeoff”firstroundeffectsandthuslimitthescopeforsecondroundeffectstomaterialize,includingthroughwageindexation.Andfirmsshouldnotbe“bitten”byhigherglobalenergypricesgiventhehomecountry’ssmallshareintheglobalenergymarket.
Evenso,theconditionsunderwhichsubsidiesreducecoreinflationstillturnouttobesurprisinglyrestrictive.Althoughsubsidieshaveessentiallynoeffectonglobalenergyprices,theycausethetradebalancetodeteriorateandexchangeratetodepreciate.Thisexchangeratechannelcanbebigenoughthatsubsidiescancausecoreinflationtorise,unlesswageindexationtoconsumerpricesissufficientlyhigh.
2
Thedepreciationeffectislargerthemorepersistentthesubsidy(whichtypicallyislinkedtothepersistenceoftheunderlyingshocktoenergysupply)andislargerineconomieswithshallowforeignexchangemarkets,asisthecaseinmanyemergingmarketeconomies.
Thepolicyimplicationisthatconsumerenergysubsidiesmayhelpreducecoreinflationifimplementedbycountriesthatarearelativelysmallshareoftheglobalenergymarket;ifthesubsidiesaretemporary;ifwageindexationtoconsumerpricesishigh(sothatsecondroundeffectswouldbelargeintheabsenceofsubsidies);andiftheactionsaretakenbyeconomieswithwell-developedfinancialmarketsandmodestdebtlevels.Theseconditionsalignwellwiththosethat
Daoetal.
(2023)foundinthecaseoftheeuroarea,wheretheyarguethat
consumerenergysubsidieshelpedmitigatebothheadlineandcoreinflationpressures
.3
Butasforeshadowedbytheclosedeconomyresults,ourtwocountrymodelhighlightshowconsumersubsidiesarelesslikelytobeeffectiveinreducinginflationastheirusebecomesmorewidespread.Thepre-subsidyenergypricerisesbymore,makingitmorelikelythatsubsidiesboostinflation.Moreover,ourmodelhighlightstheadversespilloverstootheren-ergyimporters–thelatterexperiencebiggertradedeficits,currencydepreciation,andupsideinflationpressure.Thespilloversareparticularlyacuteforvulnerableemergingeconomieswiththinforeignexchangemarkets.
Whileourfocusislargelyonaggregatesupply,consumerenergysubsidiesalsohavedemandsideeffectsthatmayvarysignificantlyacrosshouseholds,andwhicharenotwell-capturedbyourframework.Indeed,ourwelfareresultsinparticularmaybeviewedasundulybiasedagainstsuchsubsidiesinsofarthemodeldoesnotallowforhowsubsidiesmayshieldpoorerandliquidity-constrainedhouseholdsfrommajorhitstotheirpurchasingpowerandconsumptionarisingfromenergyshocks–whichwasclearlyakeyaimofpolicymakers
2Energysubsidiestendtobehelpfulundertheseconditionsbychokingofffirst-roundeffectsthatwouldotherwiseexertlargepassthroughtocore.
3Wealsoshowthatapackageofenergysubsidiestofirmsaswellashouseholdsmaybeattractiveforasmall“energy-pricetaking”economy–supportingaggregatedemandwhileloweringinflation.
inadditiontorestrainingoverallinflation.
Toexplorethis,weincorporatehand-to-mouthhouseholdsintoourclosedeconomymodelasinthetwo-agentNewKeynesian(TANK)setupdevelopedby
Galietal.
(2007)and
Bilbiie
(2008),andshowthatourresultsarelargelyrobustevenwhencapturingthedemand-sideef
-fectsofenergyshocks.
4
Interestingly,weshowthatconsumerenergysubsidiescouldimprovewelfareinourTANKframeworkbyreducingconsumptioninequalityacrosshouseholds(i.e.,permanentincomeversushand-to-mouth).However,targetedtransferstohand-to-mouthhouseholdsaremoreefficientastheycanachievethisgoalatlowerfiscalcostandwithabetterinflation-outputtradeoff.Themainadvantageofsuchtransfersoverenergysubsidiesisthattheydonotdistortrelativeenergypricesfacedbyhouseholds,andhencepreservetheirincentivetoconserveenergy.Thislimitstheincreaseinthepre-subsidyenergypricefacedbyfirms,andhencelowersinflationpressure.
Ourpaperiscloselyrelatedtoaninsightfulrecentpaperby
Auclertetal.
(2023)which
exploresthetransmissionofoilshocksinanopeneconomyHANKmodel,andtheeffectsofconsumerenergysubsidies.Theseauthorsalsoshowhowsubsidiesmaybebeneficialinreducinginflationandboostingconsumptionforanindividual“small”country,butcanhavecounterproductiveeffectsifdeployedbyabroadsetofcountries.Ourpaperdiffersfromtheirworkinseveralimportantaspects.First,theirpaperfocusesheavilyonheterogeneityacrosshouseholdsinaHANKframeworkandassociateddistributionaleffects,whereasourstudydevotesmuchmoreattentiontothesupplyside(differentwageindexationschemesratherthanassumingfullindexationofwagestoconsumerprices).Second,weincorporatefeaturesaimedatcapturingfinancialvulnerabilities(suchasthinFXmarkets)thatinfluencehowsubsidiesoperatethroughopeneconomychannels.Third,weassumethecentralbankfollowsoptimalpolicyorusesaTaylor-stylereactionfunctionthatprovidesagoodapproximation.Thisturnsouttohaveimportantimplicationsforthepass-throughofenergypriceshocksandsubsidies.Alltold,ourpaperismorepessimisticintheabilitytouseconsumerenergysubsidiessuccessfullytoreduceinflation,eveninthecaseofasmallgroupofcountries(e.g.,showinghowsubsidiescanbecounterproductivethroughtradechannels).
Ourpaperalsodrawsontheextensiveearlierliteraturestudyingthetransmissionofen-ergypriceshocks.Keyempiricalcontributionsinclude
Hamilton
(1983),
Hamilton
(2003),
BarskyandKilian
(2004),
BlanchardandGali
(2007),
Kilian
(2009),
BaumeisterandHamil-
ton
(2019),and
Ka¨nzig
(2021)
.Weuseenergysupplyshocksidentifiedinthislastpapertoanalyzethereactionofwages.Anumberofpapersincorporateenergyintostructuralmacroeconomicmodels,butdonotstudytheeffectsofenergysubsidies,see
KimandLoun-
gani
(1992),
BackusandCrucini
(2000),
LeducandSill
(2004),
Bodensteinetal.
(2011),
BlanchardandRiggi
(2013),
Bodensteinetal.
(2018),
BaqaeeandFarhi
(2019),
Gagliardone
4DebortoliandGali(2018)arguethatasimpletwo-agentNewKeynesian(TANK)modelcanbea
goodapproximationofheterogeneousagentNewKeynesian(HANK)modelsregardingthetransmissionof
aggregateshockstomacroeconomicvariables.
4
5
andGertler
(2023),and
Pieroni
(2023),amongothers.Similarlyto
Auclertetal.
(2023),the
lastpaperusesaHANKsetupwhileweoptforamoreparsimoniousTANKmodelasanextensiontocapturehouseholdheterogeneityandanalyzethescopefortransfers.BylookingattheinteractionsbetweenpriceandnominalwagerigiditywithinNewKeynesianmodels,ourworkisrelatedtotheliteratureoriginatedby
Blanchard
(1986)anddrawsparticularly
on
Ercegetal.
(2000)and
Bodensteinetal.
(2008).
Arecentcontributioninthislineby
LorenzoniandWerning
(2023)considersboththetransmissionofsupplyanddemandshocks
andoptimalpolicyinacontinuoustimeframework(withinflationinterpretedasarisingfromconflictbetweenfirmsandworkersoverwages).
Thepaperisstructuredasfollows.Section2discussestheempiricalevidenceontheeffectsofenergypriceshocks,withaspecialfocusontheresponseofwages.Section3presentsasimpleclosedeconomymodelwithenergy.Section4offersanalyticalinsightsonthetransmissionofenergypriceshocksandsubsidies.ThesearecomplementedwithquantitativesimulationsdescribedinSection5.Section6presentstheversionofthemodelwithhand-to-mouthagentsandisfollowedbyanopeneconomyextensioninSection7.Section8concludes.
2EmpiricalEvidenceonOilShocksandWageAdjustment
Inthissection,weprovideempiricalevidenceontheresponseofwagesandconsumerpricestooilpriceshocksintheUnitedStatesandtheeuroarea.
First,weidentifyasourceofoilpricemovementsthatisnotcorrelatedwithotherfun-damentalshockstoavoidreversecausalityoraomittedvariablebias.Todoso,werelyon
Ka¨nzig
(2021)whoidentifiessurprisechangesinoilfuturespricesrelatedtoOPEC’s
meetingsdecisionsaboutproductiontargets.AsKnzigmeasuresthesechangesinatight
windowaroundtheannouncements,
5
itislikelythattheycanisolatetheimpactonoilpricesoftheunexpectedcomponentofOPEC’sdeliberations–analogouslytotheliteraturethatidentifiesmonetarypolicyshocks(e.g.,
Gurkaynaketal.,
2005;
GertlerandKaradi,
2015;
NakamuraandSteinsson,
2018,amongothers).SincemarketspaycloseattentiontoOPEC’s
decisions,areversecausalityoftheglobaleconomicoutlookshouldplausiblyberuledoutbecauseitshouldalreadybepricedinatthetimeoftheannouncement.OPEC’sdecisions
arenotrandomeventsbutastheKnzigshocksmeasureonlythecomponentnotanticipated
bymarkets,theirimmediateimpactonpricesshouldreflecttheelementofthedecisionthatsurprisedmarketparticipants
.6
Adistinctadvantageofusingtheseshocksrelativetothe
5Thewindowistakentobeoneday,usingWTIcrudefuturesstartingin1983tradedattheNewYorkMercantileExchange(NYMEX),whichisoneofthemostliquidandlargestmarketforcrudeoil.Forfurtherdetails,see
Ka¨nzig
(2021)
.
6NazerandPescatori
(2022)showthatitisthesurprisecomponentoftheOPEC(orOPEC+)decisions
thataffectsthemarketsincethesamedecisioncaninducepriceresponsesofdifferentsign.
6
standardapproachpioneeredby
Kilian
(2009)istobypassthedifficultiesofdisentangling
oildemandandoilproductionshocks.Evenso,wewillshowthatourresultsalsoholdwhenusingshocksmeasuredby
BaumeisterandHamilton
(2019)
.
Theseriesofoilpricesurprisesspanningfrom1983to2019areaggregatedatquarterlyfrequencyandusedasaninstrumentinanSVARmodel.Inadditiontothestandardoilmarketvariablessuchasrealoilprices(deflatedbyeithercoreorheadlineprices),oilproduction,andglobalindustrialproduction,ourproxySVARmodelalsoincludesrealGDP,coreorheadlineCPIinflation,theshort-termpolicyrate,aswellasnominalwageinflation.Allquantitiesandrelativepricesareinlogs,thepolicyratesinpercentagepoints,whilepriceandwageinflationaremeasuredaslogdifferences.WeuseidenticalSVARspecificationsfortheUSandtheeuroarea.Appendices
A.1
and
A.2
containadditionaldetailsontheproxySVARanddatadefinitions.
OurbaselineresultsarereportedinFigures
1
and
2
fortheUSandeuroarea,respectively.AccordingtotheproxySVARfortheUS,anincreaseinoilpricesdrivenbyanoilsupplynewsshockleadstoadeclineinnominalandrealwages.
7
Moreconcretely,anoilsupply-driven10percentincreaseinoilpriceswitha2-yearhalflifeincreasescoreinflationbyabout0.1percentagepointforafewquartersandreducesthenominalwagebyabout0.2percentonimpact.Consequently,theimpliedproducerrealwage–calculatedbyaccumulatingthenominalwagegrowthimpulsesandsubtractingtheaccumulatedcoreinflationimpulses–fallsbyroughly0.3percentoverthefirst2yearsandbynearly0.6percentafter5years.ThereductioninrealwagesisinlinewithanoilsupplyshocktransmittingsimilarlytoanadverseTFPshock,withrealGDPfallingbymorethat0.4percentafter2years.Cruciallyforourfurtheranalysis,theseresultssuggeststhattheabilityofUShouseholdsandlaborunionstoachievecompensationforhigherpricesthroughhigherwagesisverylimited.
TheimpactontheeuroareaisshowninFigure
2.
WhiletheoilpricepathisalmostidenticaltothatobtainedintheSVARfortheUS,thetransmissiontootherkeymacrovariablesdiffersnotably.Mostnotably,nominalwagegrowthpersistentlyincreases.ThisfindingispossiblydrivenbymorecentralizedwagebargainingandhigherunionizationintheeuroareathanintheUS,leadingtoahigherdegreeof(explicitorimplicit)indexation
(BabaandLee,
2022)
.IncreasingwagesputsomeupwardpressureoncoreinflationandsotheECBraisestheinterestratesignificantly.ThetighterpolicystanceimpliesthattheassociatedoutputcontractionisaboutthesameasintheUS,althoughtheeuroareaeconomyislessdependentonoil.Turningtotheimpliedrealproducerwage,thepointestimateofitsimpulseresponseismodestlypositive,butnotsignificantlyso.WeinterpretthisfindingasonlymildevidenceinfavorofsomeindexationmechanismsinEuropeanwagesettingthatcompensateshouseholdsforthelossofpurchasingpowerduetoenergypriceshocks.
7Theconfidencebandsarecomputedusingamovingblockbootstrap,asproposedby
JentschandLunsford
(2019).Thismethodproducesasymptoticallyvalidconfidencebandsunderfairlymildalpha-mixingcondi
-tions.Theblocksizeissetto24anddealswiththedifferenceintheestimationandidentificationsamples.
7
Figure1:USProxy-VAREvidence:OilPriceShocks
Notes:Allvariablesareexpressedinpercentdeviations,realoilpricesaredeflatedwithcoreCPI,impliedrealwageisdefinedasaccumulatednominalwageinflationminuscoreinflation.Theconfidencebandsarethe68and90percentlevelbandsbasedon10,000bootstrapreplications.
8
Figure2:EAProxy-VAREvidence:OilPriceShocks
Notes:Allvariablesareexpressedinpercentdeviations,realoilpricesaredeflatedwithcoreCPI,impliedrealwageisdefinedasaccumulatednominalwageinflationminuscoreinflation.Theconfidencebandsarethe68and90percentlevelbandsbasedon10,000bootstrapreplications.
AsshowninAppendix
A.3
,theimpactofanoilsupplyshockonheadlineinflationisnotablystrongeronimpactinboththeUSandtheeuroarea,upto1(0.5)percentinthe
9
samequarterbutmuchlesspersistent–consistentlywithoilpricesrevertingtotheirpre-shocklevels.Evenso,theimpliedconsumerrealwage,i.e.nominalwagedividedbyheadlineCPI,fallsnotablymoreinitiallythantheproducerrealwageinFigure
1
.Thesmallerpass-throughtoheadlineinflationrelativetocoreinflationintheeuroareathanintheUScanbeatleastpartiallyexplainedbyhigherexcisetaxesonliquidfuelsandadownstreamoil
industrythattendstohavemorerigidretailprices(Ahn,
2024).Importantlyforourfurther
analysis,regardlessifweworkwithcoreorheadlineinflationintheSVAR,wefindthattheimpliedrealwageintheeuroareafallslessthanintheUS.
WehaveexaminedtherobustnessofourresultsforanumberofalternativeSVARspec-ifications.Figure
3
presentstheimpulseresponsesfortheimpliedproducerrealwage(USintheleftcolumnandeuroareaintheright),whileAppendix
A.3
reportstheresultsforallvariablesincludedineachoftheconsideredalternatives.ThefirstrowinthefigurejustrestatesourbaselineresultsfromFigures
1
and
2.
Thesecondrowreportsanalternativewhereweimposemeanreversionoftherealwageimpulseresponsesbyintroducingthisvari-abledirectlyintheSVARinsteadofnominalwagegrowthandimposingstabilityconditions.Ascanbeseen,realproducerwagesintheUSstilldeclinesignificantlyinresponsetoanenergysupplyshockwhiletheyrisesomewhat(althoughnotsignificantlyatthe90percentconfidencelevel)inEurope.
Wealsotestedforpossiblenon-linearitiesintracingtheeffectsofoilpriceshoc
温馨提示
- 1. 本站所有资源如无特殊说明,都需要本地电脑安装OFFICE2007和PDF阅读器。图纸软件为CAD,CAXA,PROE,UG,SolidWorks等.压缩文件请下载最新的WinRAR软件解压。
- 2. 本站的文档不包含任何第三方提供的附件图纸等,如果需要附件,请联系上传者。文件的所有权益归上传用户所有。
- 3. 本站RAR压缩包中若带图纸,网页内容里面会有图纸预览,若没有图纸预览就没有图纸。
- 4. 未经权益所有人同意不得将文件中的内容挪作商业或盈利用途。
- 5. 人人文库网仅提供信息存储空间,仅对用户上传内容的表现方式做保护处理,对用户上传分享的文档内容本身不做任何修改或编辑,并不能对任何下载内容负责。
- 6. 下载文件中如有侵权或不适当内容,请与我们联系,我们立即纠正。
- 7. 本站不保证下载资源的准确性、安全性和完整性, 同时也不承担用户因使用这些下载资源对自己和他人造成任何形式的伤害或损失。
最新文档
- 金融科技助推银行网点数字化转型策略
- 香蕉购销合同协议书范本
- 砂石出售合同协议书范本
- 2025秋五年级上册语文(统编版)-【27 我的长生果】作业课件
- 煤炭产品买卖合同协议书
- 健身房协议书合同
- 购房合同转卖协议书范本
- 成都智能电表项目商业计划书模板范文
- 拟定合同签约协议书怎么写
- 铅酸蓄电池公司绿色建筑方案分析(范文)
- 2025年江苏省启东市文化广电和旅游局招聘编外1人历年高频重点提升(共500题)附带答案详解
- 《普通生物学》课程期末考试复习题库及答案
- dlt-5161-2018电气装置安装工程质量检验及评定规程
- 用户生命周期管理策略-洞察分析
- 第三届中国长三角地区融资担保职业技能竞赛选拔赛试题库500题(含答案)
- 2025届安徽省A10联盟高三第二次调研数学试卷含解析
- 项目管理与工程经济决策知到智慧树章节测试课后答案2024年秋哈尔滨工程大学
- 2024年中英城市更新白皮书
- 高三英语一轮复习:节日主题的词汇复习 课件
- 中建消防工程专项施工方案
- 无创机械通气护理要点
评论
0/150
提交评论