版权说明:本文档由用户提供并上传,收益归属内容提供方,若内容存在侵权,请进行举报或认领
文档简介
EuroAreaInflationafterthePandemicandEnergyShock:Import
Prices,Profits
andWagesNiels-JakobHansen,FrederikToscani,andJingZhouWP/23/131IMFWorkingPapersdescriberesearchinprogressbytheauthor(s)andarepublishedtoelicitcommentsandtoencouragedebate.TheviewsexpressedinIMFWorkingPapersarethoseoftheauthor(s)anddonotnecessarilyrepresenttheviewsoftheIMF,itsExecutiveBoard,orIMFmanagement.2023JUN©2023InternationalMonetaryFundWP/23/131IMFWorkingPaperEuropeanDepartmentEuroAreaInflationafterthePandemicandEnergyShock:ImportPrices,ProfitsandWagesPreparedbyNiels-JakobHansen,FrederikToscani,andJingZhouAuthorizedfordistributionby
OyaCelasunJune2023IMFWorkingPapersdescriberesearchinprogressbytheauthor(s)andarepublishedtoelicitcommentsandtoencouragedebate.
TheviewsexpressedinIMFWorkingPapersarethoseoftheauthor(s)anddonotnecessarilyrepresenttheviewsoftheIMF,itsExecutiveBoard,or
IMFmanagement.ABSTRACT:
We
document
the
importance
of
import
prices
and
domestic
profits
as
a
counterpart
to
the
recentincrease
in
euro
area
inflation.
Through
a
novel
consumption
deflator
decomposition,
we
show
that
import
pricesaccount
for
40percent
of
the
average
change
in
the
consumption
deflator
over
2022Q1
–
2023Q1,
while
domesticprofits
account
for
45percent.
The
increase
in
nominal
profits
was
largest
in
sectors
benefiting
from
increasinginternational
commodity
prices
and
those
exposed
to
recent
supply-demand
mismatches.
While
the
results
showthat
firms
have
passed
on
more
than
the
nominal
cost
shock,
and
have
fared
relatively
better
than
workers,
thelimited
available
data
does
not
point
to
a
widespread
increase
in
markups.
Looking
ahead,
assuming
nominalwage
growth
of
around
4.5percent
over
2023-24
–
slightly
below
the
level
seen
in
Q1
2023
–
and
broadlyunchanged
productivity,
a
normalization
of
the
profit
share
to
the
average
level
over
2015-19
will
be
necessarytoachieve
aconvergenceof
inflationtotargetoverthenexttwoyears.Monetarypolicy
willthusneedtoremainrestrictive
to
anchor
expectations
and
maintain
subdued
demand
such
that
workers
and
firms
settle
on
relativepricesettingthatisconsistentwithdisinflation.RECOMMENDEDCITATION:
Hansen,Niels-Jakob,FrederikToscani,JingZhou.2023.“TheRoleofImportPrices,ProfitsandWagesintheCurrentInflationEpisodeintheEuroArea”IMFWorkingPaper23/131,InternationalMonetaryFund,Washington,DC.JELClassificationNumbers:Keywords:E31,E24Inflation;
Wages;
Profits;
TermsofTradeNHansen@,
Ftoscani@,Jzhou@Author’sE-MailAddress:WORKINGPAPERSINTERNATIONALMONETARYFUND2EuroAreaInflationafterthePandemicandEnergyShock:ImportPrices,ProfitsandWagesPreparedby
Niels-JakobHansen,FrederikToscani,andJingZhou11We
are
grateful
to
Oya
Celasun
for
her
guidance
and
support.
We
also
thank
Silvia
Albrizio,
Jorge
Alvarez,
Christian
Bogmans,Romain
Duval,
Nir
Klein,
Geoff
Gottlieb,
Rui
Mano,
Pierre-Olivier
Gourinchas,
Mirko
Licchetta,
Andrea
Pescatori,
Jorge
Miranda
Pinto.AlexandreBalduinoSollaci,andseminarparticipantsandreviewersattheIMFfortheirveryhelpfulcommentsandsuggestions.INTERNATIONALMONETARYFUND31.INTRODUCTION
_______________________________________________________________________________
52.DECOMPOSINGTHEGDPDEFLATOR
________________________________________________________
73.DECOMPOSINGTHECONSUMPTIONDEFLATOR
__________________________________________
114.IMPLICATIONSFORPROFITABILITYANDTHEDISTRIBUTIONOFINCOME
______________
135.IMPLICATIONSFORTHEINFLATIONOUTLOOK____________________________________________
166CONCLUSION__________________________________________________________________________________
18REFERENCES_____________________________________________________________________________________
20FIGURES1.DecompositionofChangeintheGDPDeflator
____________________________________________________________
82.SectoralProfit
______________________________________________________________________________________________
83.ComparisonofGDPDeflatorIncreasetoPreviousEnergyPriceShocks
___________________________________
94.ComparisonofEuroAreaGDPDeflatorDecompositionwithOtherMajor
_______________________________105.DecompositionofChangeintheConsumptionDeflator
_________________________________________________126..AccountingfortheContributionofProductivity
toInflation______________________________________________137.IncomeSharesandRealWageandProfit_________________________________________________________________148.ProfitabilityIndicators_____________________________________________________________________________________159.CountryCharacteristicsandIncreaseinUnitProfit________________________________________________________1610.IllustrationofInflation,WageandProfitProjections
____________________________________________________18INTERNATIONALMONETARYFUND41.IntroductionThe
increase
in
firm
profits
in
the
recent
inflation
episode
has
been
catching
the
attention
of
economiccommentatorsand
policy
makersacrossadvancedeconomies.Despitesomecross-countryheterogeneity,therehasbeenapatternof
profitsperunit
ofoutput
(unit
profits)
being
animportantcounterparttotheincreasein
the
GDP
deflator
in
advanced
economies
over
the
past
two
years.
Policy
makers
have
consequently
pivotedin
their
communication
to
highlight
the
role
of
profits
for
inflation
along
with
the
role
of
unit
labor
costs.
Forexample,
ECB
executive
board
member
Philip
Lane
in
an
interview
with
Reuters
pointed
to
“extraordinary
unitprofits”,
and
ECB
executive
board
member
Fabio
Panetta
raised
the
risk
of
a
profit-price
spiral
in
a
New
YorkTimes
interview.2
Former
IMF
chief
economist
Olivier
Blanchard
has
pointed
out
that
distributional
conflict
–
beit
driven
by
strong
aggregate
demand
or
the
initial
desire
of
one
economic
actor
to
increase
relative
prices
relativetoothers–cangenerateinflationaryprocesses.Against
this
background,
our
paper
investigates
the
role
of
profits,
wages,
and
import
prices
in
the
recentepisode
of
high
inflation
in
the
Euro
Area.
We
contribute
to
the
debate
by
disentangling
the
role
of
importprices,profits,andwagesin
inflationintheeuroarea.Focusingontheconsumptiondeflator,
we
addtheroleofimport
prices
to
the
now
well-known
GDP
deflator
decomposition.
To
set
the
scene,
we
confirm
that
unit
profitsin
the
euro
area
have
increased
sharply
and
are
the
main
counterpart
to
the
increase
in
the
GDP
deflator.
Theprofit
increase
was
largest
in
mining
and
utilities
but
was
also
significant
in
agriculture,
construction,manufacturing,
and
contact-intensive
services.
Accounting
explicitly
for
the
import
price
shock
through
aconsumption
deflator
rather
than
GDP
deflator
decomposition,
we
find
that
import
prices
account
directly
for40percentof
inflationonaveragesince2022.
Butthe
role
ofdomestic
profits
remainssignificant,accountingforjust
below
45percent
and
labor
costs
for
25percent
of
inflation.
Net
taxes
were
slightly
disinflationary
over
theperiodandthuscontributednegatively.While
nominal
profits
have
increased,
this
is
not
necessarily
true
for
profitability.
Our
results
imply
thatfirms
have
passed
on
more
than
the
immediate
nominal
import
cost
shock.
Given
the
increasing
profit
share
ofgross
value
added,
firms
have
so
far
also
been
relatively
more
shielded
from
the
adverse
terms
of
trade
shockthan
wage
earners.
But
this
does
not
necessarily
imply
that
profitability
(the
markup
or
profit
margin)
hasincreased.
Analysis
by
economists
at
the
Bank
of
Italy
(Colonna
et
al.,
2023)
carefully
lays
out
the
relationshipbetween
profit
share
and
markup
and
illustrates
the
conditions
under
which
they
can
move
in
opposite
directions.TheyalsoshowthatdataforGermanysuggestsmarkupsinindustryandinmanufacturingremainedconstantin2022,
but
increased
in
construction,
retail,
accommodation,
and
transport.
In
Italy,
markups
in
2022
wereessentially
at
pre-pandemic
levels.
Our
own
reading
of
the
limited
national
accounts-based
data
for
the
euro
areais
consistent
with
this,
pointing
to
broadly
constant
rather
than
increasing
profitability.
How
come
firms
have
beenrelativelymoreshieldedfromtheshockthanworkers?Onereasonisthatpricesare
moreflexiblethanwages—firms
are
able
to
adjust
prices
quickly
to
shield
their
profitability
while
wage
is
subject
to
more
rigidities
such
asbeingsetbypreviouswagenegotiations.The
growing
literature
on
the
role
for
profits
is
generally
aligned
with
our
finding
that
firms
have
faredrelatively
better
than
workers
even
in
the
absence
of
a
large
increase
in
markups.
For
the
euro
are,
amongothers,
authors
from
the
European
Central
Bank
(Arce
et
al.,
2023)
and
European
Stability
Mechanism(Capolongo
et
al.,
2023)
as
well
as
the
European
Commission
in
its
Spring
2023
forecast
have
shown
that
unitprofits
rose
significantly
in
2022,
leading
to
an
increase
in
the
profit
share.
Unit
profit
increases
have
been2
https://www.ecb.europa.eu/press/inter/date/2023/html/ecb.in230228~c78d1f2ca5.en.html
andhttps://www.ecb.europa.eu/press/inter/date/2023/html/ecb.in230401~ec65174af7.en.htmlINTERNATIONALMONETARYFUND5concentrated
in
sectors
exposed
to
international
commodity
prices
and
demand-supply
mismatches.
Theanalysis
most
closely
related
to
our
own
is
the
work
presented
in
speeches
by
the
Bank
of
England’s
Dhingra(2023)
and
Haskel
(2023)
which
through
somewhat
different
methodologies
decompose
inflation
into
domesticprofits,
wages,
taxes
and
imported
prices
(splitting
out
energy
costs
and
other
imported
prices
in
Dhingra’sapproach).
While
the
results
differ
somewhat
between
both
approaches,
both
caution
against
an
oversimplisticinterpretation
where
an
increase
in
gross
operating
surplus
is
interpreted
as
corporate
profits
being
the
largestdriverofinflation.
Haskelfindsalargerrolefortermsoftradeforeuroarea
inflationthanintheUKandUS,withmagnitudes
broadly
comparable
to
our
own
work
for
the
euro
area.
On
the
implications
for
profitability
andwhether
a
positive
markup
shock
has
been
a
causal
driver
of
inflation,
work
by
the
IMF
in
the
October
2022
WorldEconomic
Outlook,
does
not
find
a
broad-based
increase
markup
for
advanced
economies
in
2021.
At
the
countrylevel,
in
addition
to
Colonna
et
al.
(2023),
Glover
et
al
(2023a)
find
that
markups
in
2021
increased
3.4percentin
the
US,
contributing
significantly
to
the
increase
in
inflation.
In
a
follow-up
piece,
Glover
et
al.
(2023b)
showthat
the
contribution
of
profits
to
inflation
eased
in
the
US
in
2022,
and
that
the
pattern
has
been
in
line
withpreviouseconomicrecoveries.Werning
and
Lorenzoni
(2023)
present
a
conceptual
framework
which
can
be
used
to
think
about
inflationas
a
manifestation
of
conflict–
disagreement
about
relative
prices
–
between
economic
actors.
In
thecontextofa
largeimportpriceshockastherootcause
ofaninitialincreaseinprices,
forexample,
thiscan
leadto
a
generalized
increase
in
inflation
as
agents
sequentially
(due
to
nominal
rigidities)
adjust
prices
dependingon
their
inflation
expectations.
Blanchard
(1986)
is
an
important
contribution
on
cost
push
inflation,
where
workersattempt
to
maintain
their
purchasing
power
following
an
initial
erosion
leading
to
further
inflation.
This
can
be
auseful
angle
to
interpret
the
consumption
deflator
decomposition
we
present.
It
suggests
that
in
line
with
historicalevidence,
an
acceleration
in
labor
costs
is
likely
ahead.
From
a
more
general
perspective,
our
paper
is
looselylinked
to
the
strand
of
literature
which
analyzes
profitability
and
market
power
using
firm-level
data
(e.g.,
DeLoeckeretal(2020),Davisetal(2022))butwefocusonnationalaccountdata.Illustrative
simulations
show
that
a
compression
in
the
profit
share
to
historic
norms
will
likely
benecessaryto
achievethedisinflationaryprocess
underplausiblewagegrowthassumptions.Westartbyestimating
that
the
terms
of
trade
contribute
negatively
toinflation
in
the
euro
areaover
the
next
two
years
–
onthe
order
of
one
percentage
point
in
2023
based
on
the
assumptions
underlying
the
April
2023
IMF
WorldEconomic
Outlook.
We
also
assume
that
there
will
be
no
contribution
of
net
taxes
to
inflation
and
that
laborproductivity
will
remain
broadly
flat
in
the
next
couple
of
years.
Under
these
assumptions
we
are
able
to
mapinflation
outcomes
in
the
profit
share-nominal
wage
growth
space
using
our
consumption
deflator
decomposition.This
exercise
shows
that
average
nominal
wage
growth
of
around
4.5percent
over
2023-24
is
consistent
withthe
inflation
projections
in
the
April
2023
World
Economic
Outlook
for
the
euro
area
–
which
show
inflationconverging
to
target
in
early/mid
2025
–
if
profit
shares
return
to
the
average
level
of
2015-19
by
end-2024
andlabor
productivity
remains
broadly
unchanged.
Should
wages
increase
more
significantly
–
for
example,
in
astaticsensewagegrowthofaround5.5
percentwouldensurethatrealwagesreturntotheirpre-pandemiclevelbyend-2024–inflationwouldbenotablyhigherunlesstheprofitsharecompresses
tothelowestlevelsincethemid-1990s.
It
is
then
incumbent
on
policy
makers
to
anchor
expectations
and
support
coordination
amongeconomic
actors
on
a
low
inflation
equilibrium
such
that
the
recovery
in
real
wages
occurs
at
a
measured
paceandfirmsacceptacompressionin
theprofitshare.Thepaperproceedsasfollows.First,itlaysoutthestandardGDPdeflatordecompositionwhichhasreceivedmuchattentionoverrecentmonths.Itcomparesthecontributionofunitprofits,unitlaborcosts,andunittaxestodayintheeuroareawithhistoricalevidencefromthe1970soilpriceshocksaswellaswithothermajoreconomies.Second,theanalysismovesclosertounderstandingthedynamicsofHICPbyproposingadecompositionoftheconsumptiondeflator(whichlikeHICPbutunlikeGDPincludesimportsbutexcludesINTERNATIONALMONETARYFUND6exports).Third,wediscusswhattheresultsimplyforprofitability.Fourth,weanalyzeimplicationsfortheinflationoutlook.Thefinalsectionconcludes.2.DecomposingtheGDP
DeflatorInthissection,weexploitthatGDPfromtheincomesidecanbewrittenasthesumoflaborcompensation,grossoperatingsurplus,andnettaxes.
ItiswellknownthatGDPfromtheincomesidecanbewrittenas퐺퐷푃
=
퐺푉퐴+푁푒푡
푇푎푥푒푠
=
푃푟표푓푖푡푠
+퐶표푚푝푒푛푠푎푡푖표푛
표푓
퐸푚푝푙표푦푒푒푠
+푁푒푡
푇푎푥푒푠(2.1)FromthisitfollowsthattheGDPdeflator(nominalGDPdividedbyrealGDP)
canbeexpressedasthesumofunitlaborcosts,unitprofitsandunitnettaxes.퐺퐷푃=
퐺퐷푃
퐷푒푓푙푎푡표푟
=
푈푛푖푡
푃푟표푓푖푡푠
+푈푛푖푡
퐿푎푏표푟
퐶표푠푡
+푈푛푖푡
푇푎푥푒푠(2.2)퐺퐷푃푅Whilethisaccountingidentifydoesnotallowforanycausalinterpretation,itshowshow(changesin)theGDPdeflatorisreflectedinprofitsperunitofrealGDP(unitprofits),
laborcompensationperunitofrealGDP(unitlaborcost),andtaxeslesssubsidiesper
unitofGDP(unittaxes).ToexploittheGDPdeflator
decompositionidentity,werelyonnationalaccountsdata.
Thenationalaccountsreportprofitsasgrossoperatingsurplusandmixedincome.Operatingsurplusmeasuresthesurplusordeficitaccruingfromproductionbynonfinancialandfinancialcorporations,government,households,andnonprofitinstitutionsservinghouseholds.Mixedincomeisthesurplusordeficitaccruingfromproductionbyunincorporatedenterprisesownedbyhouseholds.Grossoperatingsurplusdiffersfromprofitsshownincompanyaccountsforseveralreasons.Onlyasubsetoftotalcostsaresubtractedfromgrossoutputtocalculatethegrossoperatingsurplus.Essentiallyitisgrossoutputlessthecostofintermediategoodsandservicestogivegrossvalueadded,andlesscompensationofemployeesandtaxesandsubsidiesonproductionandimports.Itisgrossbecauseitmakesnoallowanceforconsumptionoffixedcapital(CFC).Foreaseofnotation,wewillrefertogrossoperatingsurplus
andmixedincomeasnominalprofitsthroughoutthispaper.Profitsperunitofoutputdivergedsharplyfromtheirpre-pandemictrendinrecentquartersandwerethemaincounterpartstotheincreaseintheGDPdeflatorin2022(Figure1).
Between2000and2019,unitprofitscontributedslightlylesstotheGDPdeflatorthanunitlaborcosts,withaminorrolefor
increasingtaxes.2020and2021sawhighvolatilityincomponents,inpartduetothetemporarypandemictaxcuts,evenastheGDPdeflatorincreasedbyasteady3percentinbothyears.In2022,theGDPdeflatoracceleratedsharply,withbothunitlaborcostsandunitprofitsrisingsignificantlyaboveaveragesinrecentyears.Unitprofitscontributedthelargestshareoftheincrease.Thelatestavailabledata
atthetimeofwritingwasQ12023,showingafurtherincreaseinboththecontributionofunit
profitsandunitlaborcostsrelativetothe2022average.INTERNATIONALMONETARYFUND7Figure1.EuroArea:DecompositionofChangeintheGDPDeflatorUnitprofitsincreasedinagriculture,construction,miningandutilities,manufacturingandcontact-intensiveservices.Theminingandutilitiessectorsawthelargestincrease,whilesomesectorssuchasprofessionalsandpublicadministrationremainedbelowpre-COVIDlevels(Figure2).LookingintermsofcontributionstototalGDPdeflatorinflationsince2022,trade,travel,accommodationandfood—withasignificantincreaseinunitprofitandasizableshareintotalgrossvalueadded—sawthelargestincreaseintheirshare.Similarchangealsoappliestominingandutilities,whopreviously
contributedanegligiblesharetoGDPdeflatorinflation,now
wasresponsiblefortwotenthsoftheaverageinflationbetween2022Q1and2023Q1.Onthecontrary,manufacturing,whichusedtocontributeaquartertotheGDPdeflatorinflationinthelastdecade,onlyaccountedforaroundonetenthoftheinflation.Figure2.EuroArea:SectoralProfitINTERNATIONALMONETARYFUND8TheincreaseintheGDPdeflatorfollowingthecurrentenergyshockhasbeencomparableinmagnitudetothefirstoilpriceshockofthe1970s,butthecompositionhasbeendifferent.Followingthefirstoilpriceshockin1973
–spurredbytheOrganizationofthePetroleumExportingCountriesoilembargo–thegrowthintheGDPdeflatorrosemarkedly,drivenalmostexclusivelybyacceleratinglaborcostswhileprofitsfell(Figure
3,leftpanel).
3
Laborcostsalsoplayedmoreofaroleduringthesecondoilpriceshockin1979
–triggeredEuroArea:GDPDeflator(Percent,
year-on-year)1614121086420-2Unit
TaxUnit
ProfitUnit
Labor
CostTotal-4bythetemporaryreductioninoilsupplyamidtheIranianrevolution–althoughtheoverallincreaseintheGDPdeflatorgrowthwassmallerinthatepisode(Figure
3,middlepanel).ThemagnitudeofthecurrentincreaseintheGDPdeflatorinflationrateiscomparabletothefirstoilpriceshock(Figure
3,rightpanel),albeitfromamuchlowerstartinglevelofinflation(textchart).Profitshaveplayedalargerrolethanlaborcostssofarinthecurrentepisode(Figure3,rightpanel).However,duringallthreeepisodestherelativecontributionfromlaborcostsgrewovertime.Thisisconsistentwiththenotionthatfirmscanpassonhigherinputscostmorepromptly,whileittakesalongertimeforwagestoadjust(the
wageadjustmentswerelargeafterthefirstoilpriceshockoncetheykickerinafteraboutthree-fourquarters,likelyduetoexplicitindexationarrangementsandlessanchoredexpectations).Theresultinginitiallylowerrealwageswouldincentivizemorehiring,eventuallyalsopushingupwages.Thus,anincreaseintherelativecontributionfromwagesduring2023wouldbeconsistentwiththehistoricalevidenceandtheory.Figure3.EuroArea:ComparisonofGDPDeflatorIncreasetoPreviousEnergyPriceShocksSources:OECD;Eurostat;theAreawideDatabase;IMFstaffcalculations.RelativetotheUSandCanada,theincreaseintheGDPdeflatorintheeuroareahasrecentlybeenmoretiltedtowardsprofits.InCanadaandtheUnitedStates,theaccelerationintheGDPdeflatorstartedearlierandwasmorebiasedtowardshigherlaborcosts(Figure
4).Onayear-on-yearbasistheGDPdeflatorhasdeceleratedinbothcountriesinthesecondhalfof2022.IntheeuroareaandtheUK,ontheotherhand,theGDPdeflatoracceleratedpreciselyinthesecondhalfof2022,withalargeroleplayedbyprofits.Thiscouldpartlyreflectthedifferentnatureofshocks,withtheshockinNorthAmericabeingrelativelymore
drivenbydemand(andapositivetermsoftradeshockin2022)whiletheadverseenergyshockplayedanimportantroleintheeuroareaandUK.TakingalongerperspectivetounderstandthecumulativeGDPdeflatorchangeover3
Nominal(unit)profitsincreasedsharplyintheyearsjustbeforetheoilpriceshock(1971-1973).Theoutsizedroleoflaborcosts'followingtheoilshockmightthushavepartlybeenareactiontothisincrease.INTERNATIONALMONETARYFUND9boththepandemicandenergyshockperiod(Q42019toQ42022),showsthatprofitsplayedthelargestroleintheEuroAreainrelativeterms(Figure4).4Figure4.EuroArea:ComparisonofEuroAreaGDPDeflatorDecompositionwithOtherMajorEconomiesUnitedStates:GDPDeflator(Percent,
year-on-year)151050-5-10-15UnitprofitsUnitlaborcostUnittaxTotalSources:OECD;Eurostat;theAreawideDatabase;IMFstaffcalculations.Notes:FortheUnitedStates,thebarsdonotsumuptothefulldeflatorgrowthineachquarter,asprofits,nettaxes,and
laborcostheresumtogrossdomestic
income.4
IMF(2022)hadaboxwithasimilarexerciseoncontributionstocumulativeGDPdeflatorchanges,however,the
periodcoveredwas2019q4-2021q4.INTERNATIONALMONETARYFUND103.DecomposingtheConsumptionDeflatorConceptually,theGDPdeflatordoesnotprovideafullpictureoftherecentepisodeofsurging
consumerpriceinflationsinceitincludesexportpricesandexcludesimportprices.Onaverage,differentmeasuresofpricechangesintheeconomysuchastheGDPdeflator,thetotalconsumptiondeflatorandHICP/CPIinflationtendtoco-moveclosely(textchart).However,attimesoflargeterms-of-tradeswingstheycandecouple,andthishasbeenthecaseovertherecentyears.ThelinkbetweentheconsumptiondeflatorandHICPdevelopmentsistighter,sincetheybothincludeimportpricesofconsumergoodsandunliketheGDPdeflatorexcludeexportprices.Usingasetofsimplifyingassumptions,consumerpriceinflationcan
bedecomposedintocontributionsfrom
domesticprofits,labor,foreign,and
nettaxes.AssumethattheproductionfunctiontoproducetotalconsumptionisCobb-Douglas,withweight휆
forvalueaddedfromcountry푗
sector푠
(∑푗,푠
휆푗푠=푗푠1).Thecostminimizationproblemforproduceris:min
∑
푝
푞푞푠.
푡.
∏(푞
)휆푗푠
=
1푗푠
푗푠푗푠푗푠푗,푠푗,푠Theresultingproducercostforoneunitoftotalconsumptionisequalto휆푗푠푝∏
(
푗푠)휆푗푠푗,푠andtheshareofthecostofgoodsfromcountry푗
sector푠
inthetotalcostamountsto휆
.Assumingthatretailer푗푠takesaconstantmarkup(correspondingtoaconstantelasticityofsubstitutionbetweengoodsinconsumer’sutilityfunction),thenthedynamicsofconsumptiondeflatorinflationmimicthoseofproducerpricescombinedwithasalestax휏.휆푗푠푝푝
=
(1+휏)
∏
(
푗푠)휆푗푠푗,푠Consumptiondeflatorinflationcanbewrittenas:ln
푝
−ln
푝̃
=
∑푗,푠
휆
(ln
푝
−ln
푝̃
)+ln(1+휏)−ln(1+휏̃)(3.1)푗푠푗푠푗푠̃where
denotesvalueofagivenvariableinthelastperiod.Essentially,(ln
푝푗푠
−ln
푝̃
)
canbecalculatedfrom푗푠theGVAdeflatorinflationofcountry푗
sector푠,whichcanbedecomposedintolaborcompensation(퐿)andprofit(퐹)usingrealGVA(푦)andgroupedintodomesticprofit,domesticla
温馨提示
- 1. 本站所有资源如无特殊说明,都需要本地电脑安装OFFICE2007和PDF阅读器。图纸软件为CAD,CAXA,PROE,UG,SolidWorks等.压缩文件请下载最新的WinRAR软件解压。
- 2. 本站的文档不包含任何第三方提供的附件图纸等,如果需要附件,请联系上传者。文件的所有权益归上传用户所有。
- 3. 本站RAR压缩包中若带图纸,网页内容里面会有图纸预览,若没有图纸预览就没有图纸。
- 4. 未经权益所有人同意不得将文件中的内容挪作商业或盈利用途。
- 5. 人人文库网仅提供信息存储空间,仅对用户上传内容的表现方式做保护处理,对用户上传分享的文档内容本身不做任何修改或编辑,并不能对任何下载内容负责。
- 6. 下载文件中如有侵权或不适当内容,请与我们联系,我们立即纠正。
- 7. 本站不保证下载资源的准确性、安全性和完整性, 同时也不承担用户因使用这些下载资源对自己和他人造成任何形式的伤害或损失。
评论
0/150
提交评论