The relationship between international trade and economic growth has_第1页
The relationship between international trade and economic growth has_第2页
The relationship between international trade and economic growth has_第3页
The relationship between international trade and economic growth has_第4页
The relationship between international trade and economic growth has_第5页
已阅读5页,还剩41页未读 继续免费阅读

下载本文档

版权说明:本文档由用户提供并上传,收益归属内容提供方,若内容存在侵权,请进行举报或认领

文档简介

1、preliminary do not quotecomments welcomeshuo.jan.davethe link between trade and income: export effect, import effect, or both?shuo zhangjan ondrichj. david richardson department of economics, 110 eggers hall, syracuse, new york 13244. all responsibility for errors remains with the authors. departmen

2、t of economicssyracuse universitymarch 2003abstracta new framework is developed to evaluate how cross-country differences in export openness and import openness in 1990 affected the level of real per capita income. familiar and novel instruments are used to extract the exogenous components of total

3、trade (exports plus imports) and of net exports (exports minus imports), which in turn imply distinct export and import effects. we build on an existing literature (frankel-romer and others) that uses aspects of a countrys geography as instrumental variables for total trade openness. we build on a c

4、ountrys demography and net wealth abroad to develop a novel instrument for net export openness. our new estimates reveal that export openness alone correlates with income cross-sectionally, not import openness. i.introductionthe doctrine of mercantilism views trade, at least in part, as a zero-sum g

5、ame. trade is considered favorable if exports bring in more money than what is paid out for imports. adam smith and david ricardo challenged the mercantilism theory by arguing that overall openness is what matters nations grow more prosperous through the process of specialization and trade through i

6、mports as well as exports. many developing countries have replaced their strategy of government-protected import substitution industrialization with a market-focused export oriented strategy. they seek to promote economic growth by exporting more and more of their products; this has the feel of neo-

7、mercantilism. this paper re-poses the question whether trade “raises” a countrys income per person (or per worker); and if it does, what are the channels through which trade affects income, exports or imports? numerous theoretical and empirical studies have attempted to answer these questions. theor

8、etical support for the positive link between different sorts of openness and economic growth were provided by romer (1986) and lucas (1988). barro and sala-i-martin (1995) and romer (1992) emphasized how countries that are more open have a greater ability to absorb (import) technological advances, w

9、hich ultimately leads to higher real per capita income. krugman (1974), rodrik (1995), and rodriguez and rodrik (2000) on the other hand, cast doubt on the impact of openness on growth. warner (2003) casts doubt on their doubts and views our central question as a frontier issue. “proposition to be a

10、ssessed 10. passive liberalization balanced export and import openness works but only assures moderate growth; fast growth requires more active liberalization-promoting exports rather than just creating an enabling environment for open trade.” warner (2003), pp. 20. empirical studies construct measu

11、res of openness variable based on exports see krueger (1978), balassa (1978), feder (1982) for some of the earliest studies, and the collection of asian-miracle (re)considerations in stiglitz and yusuf (2000) for more recent references. micro-data studies that correlate firm performance with export

12、openness are summarized in lewis and richardson (2001). , imports see ram (1990), masumdar (2000), mody and yilmax (2002). micro-data studies that correlate firm performance with import openness include ozler and yilmax (2000), pavcnik (2000), and levinsohn (2003). , or the sum of the exports and im

13、ports for example, franker and romer (1999) and harrison (1996) are based on the assumption that the coefficients on exports and imports are the same. . levine and renelt (1992) argue that “all findings using the share of exports in gdp could be obtained almost identically using the total trade or i

14、mport share. thus, studies that use export indicators should not be interpreted as studying the relationship between growth and exports per se but rather as studying the relationship between growth and trade defined more broadly.” (p.959) grossman and helpman (1991) stated that technological spillov

15、ers could come via imports as easily as exports. lawrence and weinstein (2001) argue that imports, not exports, contribute importantly to the productivity growth of japan and korea. frankel and romer (1999), on which chapter one of this dissertation is based (zhang 2002a), alleviates many of the con

16、ceptual and econometric barriers to these issues by showing how geographical characteristics provide an arguably good instrument for a countrys intrinsic openness. yet they remark that their trade and income investigation cannot separate the import effect and export effect. wei (with wu 2001, 2002a,

17、 2002b) consciously follows frankels and romers lead in a study of how globalization affects chinese city-level growth and inequality. wei conflates export and import influences by selecting chinese cities distanced to two major chinese ports as his instrument for a citys natural openness. no one to

18、 our knowledge has yet figured a way to do what seems initially the most natural thing. that is to construct a measure of export openness, then an arguably independent measure of import openness, and investigate whether one has a different effect on income than the other, ceteris paribus. that is th

19、e principal objective of this paper - to identify the separate influences of export openness and import openness on income levels after controlling for endogeneity. in particular, we develop a framework that is slightly different from the frankel and romer (1999) income determination model by consid

20、ering an additional “net trade effect” on income levels. when combined with frankel and romers “total-trade” effect, the two effects together imply separable export and import effects. the extended income model is intended to contribute to three empirical challenges related to trade and income. the

21、first is the frankel-romer determination of instruments for total trade. the second is the determination of instruments for net trade. thirdly, the model and data employed permit the identification of the impact of exports and imports on income separately. our concern about endogeneity in this chapt

22、er differs slightly from our concern in the previous chapter. when considering exports and imports separately, the expected bias from ignoring endogeneity is, respectively, caused by the unobserved income determinants that are correlated with exports and imports. this paper (zhang 2002b) is one part

23、 of my three dissertation papers (zhang 2002a, zhang 2002b, zhang 2003). zhang (2002a) explores the sensitivity of the frankel and romer (1999) empirical relationship between countrys total-trade openness and income level to heteroscedasticity and sample selection in their first-stage bilateral inst

24、rumenting regressions. the results support their hypothesis that trade has a significant and positive, yet relatively small impact on income. the present chapter tries to differentiate frankels and romers export openness from import openness. export openness plays the dominant role. unfortunately, t

25、he unique instrumenting techniques for “net trade” in this chapter cannot be implemented bilaterally, so there remains some doubt about the exact onformity of our conclusions to frankel and romers. zhang (2003) employs established and new panel econometrics techniques to further examine the robustne

26、ss of the findings presented in frankel and romer (1999), zhang (2002a), zhang (2002b) and other literature. the rest of the paper is as follows. section ii describes the models. section iii provides data definitions and sources. section iv reports the empirical results and section vi contains the c

27、onclusions of the paper. ii.empirical modelsextensive research has been devoted to investigating factors that influence the per-capita income levels of countries. recently, an enormous literature has developed on the influence of trade openness. see notes 3 through 5 above. plus, dollar (1992), sach

28、s and warner (1995), and edwards (1998) find significant relationship between the lower barriers to trade and higher growth. both on theoretical and empirical grounds, rodriguez and rodrik (2000) cast doubt on the robustness of this linkeage. the major shortcoming of many of these empirical studies

29、is their inability to separate the impact of exports and imports. some focus on one to the neglect of the other; others focus on openness measures that force them to have equal weight. in particular, by regressing income on total trade, many studies embody an underlying assumption that exports and i

30、mports contribute equally to income growth. in this section, we develop a simple model based on one of them, the frankel-romer study, by separating the total trade share into export share and import share in order to distinguish between export effect and import effect. (1)where represents per capita

31、 income. and are exports and imports scaled by real gdp. the scaling introduces special estimation challenges, discussed below. stands for other control variables. as written, the “true” effects of export openness and import openness, respectively, are and . yet in practice, researchers usually omit

32、 one of the openness terms or force the coefficients to be identical on the two measures of openness (calling the sum of the two “overall” or total “openness”). in principle, this could cause omitted-variable bias in the remaining coefficients of interest or specification bias, due to constraining t

33、wo coefficients to have the same value. yet the natural temptation to “just run equation (1)” usually creates misleading inferences because export openness and import openness are indeed highly correlated, as any general-equilibrium thinker knows and as levine and renelt observe (above), and because

34、 both are acknowledged to be endogenously related income per capita, the focus variable on which they are thought to “operate.” focusing on the cases of japan and korea, lawrence and weinstein (2001) found that imports rather than exports are the beneficial conduit of faster productivity growth. how

35、ever, directly using the import and export variables on the right hand side of the regression function as they did may have led to inconsistent estimates due to the effect of reverse causation. confronting these challenges, whats a researcher to do? both exports and imports contribute to income grow

36、th. exports promote specialization and exploit economies of scale. an increase in demand for countrys output raises real income. imports allow countries to take advantage of other countries technology embodied in imported inputs. through intensive involvement in international competition, countries

37、become more productive. but income also has a causal effect on exports and imports. more supply of output leads potentially to more exports. higher income facilitates consumption of both domestic and foreign products which ultimately raises imports. therefore, we cannot directly regress income on ex

38、ports and imports as shown in equation (1). standard regression is inconsistent in the presence of mutual endogeneity. instrumental variable estimation provides a theoretically appealing way to handle the endogeneity problem. the important practical question posed in this paper is how to find two se

39、ts of instrumenting variables that can not only capture the exogenous components of exports and imports but also distinguish the export effect from the import effect. country as exports to country b is country bs imports from country a. there is a tendency both within countries and across them for e

40、xports and imports to co-vary for general-equilibrium reasons. thus it is difficult in practice for instrumental-variable groups to ideally capture the distinction. this paper proposes an alternative method to distinguishing the effects of imports and exports. the challenge of endogeneity in standar

41、d models is maintained by algebraically re-arranging equation (1). letting t be the total trade (exports plus imports) divided by real gdp and e be the net trade (exports less imports) divided by real gdp, to control for scale effects, equation (1) transforms to(2)we argue that finding good instrume

42、nts for t and e in order to estimate equation (2) is much easier than finding good instruments for x and m in order to estimate equation (1). in figure 1, the average export share x from 1970 to 1998 is plotted against the average import share m from 1970 to 1998. the world development indicator 200

43、0 data cover 174 countries. the observations on netherlands antilles (x = 495%, m = 486%, t = 981%, e = 9%) are dropped for graphical purpose. the figure exhibits a strong positive relationship between export share and import share (with the correlation of 0.85). in figure 2, we plot the sum of the

44、export share and the import share along the vertical axis. along the horizontal axis, we plot the difference between the export share and the import share. the chart shows no evident relationship between the two variables in the long run (the correlation is equal to -0.13.) frankel and romer (1999)

45、have already provided good instrument candidates for the total trade share. the major task of the next section is to present the frankel-romer model with the heteroscedasticity correction, propose instruments for the net trade share variable by capturing cross-country differences in borrowing and le

46、nding behavior, and investigate the impact of total trade and net trade on income after instrumenting for both endogenous independent variables. since and , the estimation will shed implicit light on the distinctive export effect and the distinctive import effect. a. bilateral trade regressiontrade

47、promotes growth through increased specialization, efficient resource allocation, diffusion of international knowledge, and heightened domestic competition (sachs and warner 1995). on the other hand, countries that produce more output tend to trade more with the rest of the world. to correct for the

48、simultaneity bias, frankel and romer (1999) proposed the geographical characteristics of countries as instruments for total trade. they argued that geography is a powerful determinant of bilateral trade as well as overall trade. furthermore, countries geographical features are not affected by their

49、incomes, or by government policies and other factors that influence income. this section applies the extended version of the frankel-romer bilateral trade model as appeared in frankel and rose (2002). we also employ the updated bilateral trade data set which “is estimated to cover at least 98 percen

50、t of all trade.” (frankel and rose 2002, pp. 462) the first stage regression is based on the international trade extension of the gravity model, namely, that trade volume between two trading partners rises with an increase of national incomes or a reduction of the distance between them: (3) .in equa

51、tion (3), denotes the bilateral trade between countries i and j (measured as exports plus imports), a is the vector of coefficients, xij is the vector of the covariates, distij measures the great circle distance between the principle cities of countries i and j, pop and area represent population and

52、 area respectively, languageij is a dummy variable which takes the value of 1 if people in country i and country j speak the same language, landlockedij is the number of landlocked countries within the country pair, and borderij is the dummy variable for a common border between two countries. countr

53、ies far away from each other tend to trade less. since country size is inversely related to proximity, the impact of area is expected to be negative. larger trading partners population implies higher demand for the domestic countrys export. thus, the sign for popj should be positive. countries are e

54、xpected to trade more with each other if they have the same official language or share a border. if countries have access to the ocean, shipping costs are significantly reduced which makes it less difficult to trade. due to the possibility of heteroscedasticity in large cross-country analysis, this

55、paper conducts the breusch-pagan test on equation (3). the test statistic rejects the homoscedasticity assumption with a high level of confidence. to counteract the problem of heteroscedasticity, weighted least square (wls) estimation is used based on the procedure proposed by harvey (1976). we also

56、 adopt the robust ordinary least square (rols) estimation to correct for heteroscedascity by applying the huber-white sandwich estimator of variance in place of the traditional variance calculation (huber 1967, white 1982). this approach allows the correlation of errors for any one country, while er

57、rors between countries remain uncorrelated. rols generates similar results as we have derived using ols and wls. assuming the variance of the disturbance term in equation (3) has the following hypothesized specification: (4)the estimator of is:(5)based on the estimation(6)where is the residual resul

58、ting from the ols regression of equation (3) and . the values of both the dependent and independent variables are divided by the square root of the predicted variance of the disturbance term, which corresponds to the pattern of the residuals. this normalizes the residuals so that they are homoscedastic. the next step is to obtain the predicted value of the dependent variable in levels. simply exponentiating underestimates the expected value of because (7)where is the expected value of , which is greater than unity. thus

温馨提示

  • 1. 本站所有资源如无特殊说明,都需要本地电脑安装OFFICE2007和PDF阅读器。图纸软件为CAD,CAXA,PROE,UG,SolidWorks等.压缩文件请下载最新的WinRAR软件解压。
  • 2. 本站的文档不包含任何第三方提供的附件图纸等,如果需要附件,请联系上传者。文件的所有权益归上传用户所有。
  • 3. 本站RAR压缩包中若带图纸,网页内容里面会有图纸预览,若没有图纸预览就没有图纸。
  • 4. 未经权益所有人同意不得将文件中的内容挪作商业或盈利用途。
  • 5. 人人文库网仅提供信息存储空间,仅对用户上传内容的表现方式做保护处理,对用户上传分享的文档内容本身不做任何修改或编辑,并不能对任何下载内容负责。
  • 6. 下载文件中如有侵权或不适当内容,请与我们联系,我们立即纠正。
  • 7. 本站不保证下载资源的准确性、安全性和完整性, 同时也不承担用户因使用这些下载资源对自己和他人造成任何形式的伤害或损失。

评论

0/150

提交评论